The Geopolitics and Political
Economy of U.S. Imperialism
excerpted from the book
Pox Americana
Exposing the American Empire
Edited by John Bellamy Foster
and Robert W. McChesney
Monthly Review Press, 2004, paper
The New Geopolitics
Michael Klare
p53
Dick Cheney and some prominent neoconservatives especially, but
also Democrats such as Zbigniew Brzezinski, speak in this manner.
They openly It state that the United States is engaged in a struggle
to maintain its power vis-a-vis other contending great powers
and that America must prevail.
Now, you might ask, what contending great
powers? It might seem far from obvious that any exist. But if
you read what these folks write and hear what they say, you will
find that they are absolutely obsessed by the potential emergence
of rival great powers: Russia, China, a European combination of
some sort, Japan, and even India.
This is the essence of the Wolfowitz Doctrine,
first articulated in the Pentagon's Defense Planning Guidance
document for 1994-1999, first leaked to the press in February
1992. This document calls for proactive U.S. military intervention
to deter and prevent the rise of a contending competitor and asserts
that the United States must use any and all means necessary to
prevent that from happening....
... the doctrine lingered in the think-tank
writings of the 1990s, reemerging as the official global military
policy of the Bush II administration. It has now been incorporated
as the core principle of the document known as the National Security
Strategy of the United States of America (September 2002), available
for download from the White House website. This document states
explicitly that the ultimate purpose of American power is to prevent
the rise of a competing great power, and that the United States
shall use any means necessary to prevent that from happening,
including preventive military force when needed, but also through
spending so much money on defense that no peer competitor can
ever arise.
Against this background, it can hardly
be questioned that the purpose of the war in Iraq is to redraw
the geopolitical map of Eurasia to insure and embed U.S. power
and dominance in the region vis-a-vis these other potential competitors.
p54
... U.S. elites have concluded that the European and East Asian
rimlands of Eurasia are securely in American hands or less important,
or both. The new center of geopolitical competition, as they see
it, is south-central Eurasia, encompassing the Persian Gulf area,
which possesses two-thirds of the world's oil, the Caspian Sea
basin, which has a large chunk of what's left, and the surrounding
countries of Central Asia. This is the new center of world struggle
and conflict, and the Bush administration is determined that the
United States shall dominate and control this critical area.
Until now, the contested rimlands of Eurasia
were the base of U.S. power, while in the south-central region
there was but a very modest presence of U.S. forces. Since the
end of the Cold War, however, the primary U.S. military realignment
has entailed the drawdown of American forces in East Asia and
Europe along with the buildup of forces in the south-central region.
U.S. bases in Europe are being closed, while new military bases
are being established in the Persian Gulf area and in Central
Asia.
It is important to note that this is a
process that began before 9/11. September ii quickened the process
and gave it a popular mandate, but this was entirely serendipitous
from the point of view of U.S. strategists. It was President Clinton
who initiated U.S. military ties with Kazakhstan, Uzbekistan,
Georgia, and Azerbaijan, and who built up the U.S. capacity to
intervene in the Persian Gulf-Caspian Sea area. The U.S. invasion
of Iraq was not a victory of Wolfowitz and Rumsfeld; it was Clinton's
work that made this victory possible.
The war against Iraq was intended to provide
the United States with a dominant position in the Persian Gulf
region and to serve as a springboard for further conquests and
assertion of power in the region. It was aimed as much, if not
more, at China, Russia, and Europe as at Syria or Iran. It is
part of a larger process of asserting dominant U.S. power in south-central
Eurasia, in the very heartland of this mega-continent.
But why specifically the Persian Gulf/Caspian
Sea area, and why now? In part, because this is where most of
the world's remaining oil is located - approximately 70 percent
of known petroleum reserves. And you have to think of oil not
just as a source of fuel - although that's very important-but
as a source of power. As U.S. strategists see it, whoever controls
Persian Gulf oil controls the world's economy and, therefore,
has the ultimate lever over all competing powers.
***
U.S. Hegemony Today
p63
... the United States never really had a free trade approach to
international economics, nor a multilateralist approach. The basic
tradition was to open others' markets to whatever sectors U.S.
business was strongest in, while protecting U.S. sectors which
faced superior competitors. The U.S. principle was reciprocity
rather than most-favored-nation multilateralism. And this tradition
persisted throughout the postwar period.
p64
Very important in ensuring leadership in new growth sectors is
American industrial policy, and not least the role of the military
budget in such policy. This can fund research and development
which can generate new growth technologies. It can also prime
the pump with large military-related investments in relevant infrastructure
and with the U.S. state acting as an initial market for the products.
No other core capitalist country has an equivalent set of instruments
for launching new growth sector technologies.
p65
Some believe that these gigantic swings in exchange rates are
steered not by governments but by financial markets and foreign
exchange markets. This is ' superficially true but actually false.
These markets are situated principally in New York and its London
satellite. The biggest players in these markets take their cue
in exchange rate issues from every word and gesture of the Treasury
Department's authorities and every move by the authorities of
the Federal Reserve Bank of New York. And since the two sides
share fundamentally common interests, the U.S. Treasury Department
can use the main financial market operators precisely as instruments
and multipliers of public policy.
The full force of this power to swing
the dollar's value in great arcs can be appreciated when we remember
the consequences of the dollar's role as the main monetary unit
of account and as the main means of payment for oil and many other
international products. However much the dollar swings one way
or the other, prices do not change for these products for those
operating in the dollar zone. Furthermore, because of the dollar's
dominance as a means of payment, the United States can run up
huge current account deficits and enormous external debts without
facing the kind of monetary payments constraints facing other
states.
The dominance of the dollar is not simply
the result of the size of the U.S. economy. It is also and importantly
the result of two other things: politics and finance. A state
that protects regimes and trade routes all over the world can,
as Britain showed with its sterling area, gain the privileges
of having a world money. So can the United States. A state that
controls the sources of world oil politically can ensure that
oil is priced and largely paid for in its currency-in this case,
in dollars-and thus can defend its international dominance. And
a state which is the most politically secure in the world is a
very safe place for storing financial property, thus ensuring
huge inflows of funds into financial capital-in this case, New
York and its London (offshore) satellite. And a state with the
largest, most liquid financial market in the world is the least
risky place to store wealth since you can swiftly move your wealth
out for other purposes in such large, liquid markets.
p68
Changes were also sought in the institutional structure of capitalism
to ensure that industrial companies were dependent on securities
markets and to ensure that hostile takeovers were permitted, with
the intent that productive assets across the capitalist world
would fall into American ownership and a vast transnational centralization
of capital would be possible. And in conditions of generalized
capitalist stagnation and crisis in much of the world, paradoxically
governments and banks and industrial companies were desperate
for American finance to tide them over, giving American finance
capitalism ever widening circles of control over international
capitalism. International monetary instability greatly enhanced
these possibilities.
The drive to transform capitalism across
the capitalist world into a new private-finance-centered social
system increasingly integrated into an international capitalism
dominated by the DWSR [Dollar Wall Street Regime] has continued
for twenty years. It is widely assumed that the entire capitalist
core has accepted this drive and changed accordingly. The idea
of a globalized economy governed by neoliberalism expresses this
assumption. Yet in reality we have seen relations between capitalist
centers become much more tension-ridden, despite the fact that
in all centers there has been a drive to shift social power from
labor to capital. The concept of neoliberalism captures the generalized
drive against the social power of labor. But it does not capture
the parallel tension-ridden relations between the three main centers
of capitalism.
Although the West European states and
Japan have liberalized financial systems, scrapped capital controls,
and accepted the forcing open of other financial systems and service
sectors through the Word Trade Organization (WTO) and other mechanisms,
neither the West Europeans nor the East Asians have fully embraced
the U.S. model and the U.S. program for the world economy. The
West Europeans built a regional monetary shield against the dollar
system and combined an adaptive deal with the United States on
the WTO with efforts greatly to strengthen their own economic
and regulatory integration through the European Union (EU). And
in East Asia there have been strong reactive tendencies towards
regional networks.
Neither in Western Europe nor in East
Asia have these defensive reactions been taken on behalf of labor.
Far from it. The West European regionalist defense mechanisms
have also been mechanisms for eroding the social power of labor,
most obviously in the policy framework for the euro, which is
patently geared toward driving through a qualitative weakening
of the rights and bargaining strength of labor, particularly in
Germany.
No other capitalist center has advanced
an alternative program for international capital accumulation
or proclaimed its own capitalism as an alternative model to that
of the United States. Only through the emergence of such an alternative
can the advance of the U.S. model be checked or defeated. And
indeed, the risks of advancing such an alternative would be very
great. It could after all stimulate labor to join the challenge.
It could split the capitalist core's approach to the South in
political economy matters, opening the way toward resistance to
common transatlantic economic interests in the South. And above
all it could delegitimize the American model even within the United
States itself. These possible consequences ensure that any important
center offering an alternative would face ferocious resistance
from the United States and its transnational supporters.
The fact that neither the German nor the
Japanese capitalist classes and states have embraced the new American
system is extremely important and it is all the more remarkable
given the gigantic pressures from the 1995-2000 American boom.
But the boom has now turned out to have been a bubble, and the
American bubble has turned out to have involved a great deal of
parasitic and predatory activity, undermining the American productive
base, as in the paradigmatic case of Enron. This marks a substantial
setback for the drive to reorganize American and international
capitalism to assure U.S. capitalist dominance through the first
half of the twenty-first century.
p70
Critically, the EU was the main instrument for transforming social
relations within its member states in a "neoliberal"
direction. The basic idea was to use European social democratic
enthusiasm for European unity against European social democratic
commitment to labor rights. But in the 1990s, the European economies
were stagnating with high unemployment and the EU lacked any genuine
democratic legitimacy. Therefore, to enhance the authority of
the EU in pursuit of neoliberalism, new policy areas and activities
were sought which would appeal to the European center-left. Many
of these were in the international political field: campaigns
on human rights, environmentalism, arms control, aid, and a host
of other such causes. No longer legitimating the EU as a social
model for the world, the EU states sought to legitimate it as
the supreme global champion of the pacification of the world through
international law rather than through power politics.
p71
The ideological basis for the projection of American military
power during the Cold War had been the supposed massive military
threat from the Soviet bloc and Communism. This was largely accepted
as legitimating the aggressive use of military coercion against
pro-Soviet forces and regimes. But with the end of the Cold War,
the aggressive use of U.S. military power faced serious legitimation
problems. Many voices were raised for military aggression to be
outlawed unless it was expressly sanctioned by the Security Council,
as laid down in the U.N. Charter. And West European governments
supported this line. Attempts by the Clinton administration to
identify a new string of enemies-the so-called rogue states, dubbed
such in 1994-were branded by many, including European governments,
as exaggerated and inappropriate, and efforts by the U.S. government
to enforce sanctions against Iran and Libya as well as Cuba were
flouted by U.S. allies in Western Europe while the blockade against
Iraq was also challenged.
This West European effort to place political-legal
constraints on the U.S. use of its major political instrument-its
capacity for military aggression-contained the seeds of a new-world-
order concept which was potentially very attractive to other capitalist
states but thoroughly subversive of the entire way in which the
American state is configured. The West European idea, expressed
most cogently by German policy elites, is that the Atlantic world
should dominate the rest of the world by means of international
public law. The Atlantic states, following the example of West
European integration, should voluntarily subordinate themselves
to international legal rules constraining their sovereign autonomy.
They should then ask others wishing access to their markets and
close political relations to subordinate themselves to the same
rules. And states which egregiously flout the norms supposedly
underlying the rules of the international system should then be
subject to coercive sanctions, including, but only as a final
resort approved by the Security Council, military force. The imperial
secret of the whole concept lies in who writes the rules. If they
are written by the Atlantic states, they can dress them up as
being universalist- liberal, norm-based rules, while in reality
they are simply "positive law" rules serving the interests
of the Atlantic states. The model here is, of course, the European-inspired
WTO which presents its rules as rooted in universalist-liberal
free trade norms while in fact they are a concoction of positive-law
rules serving Atlantic capitalist interests. Under this world-order
concept, military coercive power operates not in opposition to
international law but as its enforcer.
Yet the United States has no tradition
of subordinating itself to international treaty-based law, and
it has no interest in a world order in which military force becomes
operational only as a last resort.
p73
While the U.S. capitalist class and its political leaders were
overwhelmingly committed to maintaining and extending U.S. political
dominance and the continued expansion of U.S. capitals on a global
scale, the end of the Cold War raised the threat of the U.S. electorate
demanding that U.S. government reallocate resources from the military
field and overseas expansion to tackling problems at home. Though
committed to rebuilding U.S. global political dominance, the Clinton
administration did not attempt to mobilize a broad popular constituency
for power projection abroad.
p73
A final consequence of the Soviet bloc collapse for American political
leverage was the following paradox: America was the purest of
symbols of capitalism and thus the defeat of Communism should
have greatly enhanced, and in many ways did enhance, the attractive
power of the American capitalist model. Yet at the same time,
the deepest source of American political power during the postwar
period lay in the fact that capitalist classes throughout the
world knew that they could rely upon the United States to help
crush labor or socialist challenges to their power.
p75
The Bush administration came into office determined to crack the
Europeanist nut. September 11, 2001, gave it the opportunity.
It announced a new strategic doctrine which utterly repudiated
the entire Europeanist position on world order. The new strategic
doctrine focused on the legitimate use of force, rogue states,
and the politics of the Middle East. The Bush administration then
called for war against Iraq as an operationalization of this strategic
doctrine. It turned to the West European states and asked them
if they wished to get on the bandwagon this time, adding that
they faced only two choices: being for the United States or against
it.
Senator Joseph Lieberman and all the other
leading Democrats either supported this line or went along with
it. Bush was acting firmly within the programmatic and strategic
consensus of the American capitalist class since 1990. Cheney
is not a marginal figure; he is a central figure among American
class political leaders.
The American attack on Iraq had a number
of objectives, in the region and on a global scale (including
U.S. control of world oil). But among the global targets, ending
the growing cohesion and influence of Western Europe was central.
The war has split Western Europe as intended
...
***
The Global Minotaur
Joseph Halevi and Yanis Varoufakis
p83
A ... silver lining for the United States, following the uncontrollable
rise of oil prices in the 1970s, was the massive rise in interest
rates spearheaded by spiraling inflation. As central banks struggled
to keep the lid on prices, interest rates went through the roof.
Setting aside for the moment the worldwide, overwhelming recessionary
effects of this development, the rise of interest rates was more
effective in destroying the enemies of U.S. foreign policy around
the globe than any military operation the United States could
ever imagine. Arguably, the chain of events that led to the implosion
of Communism in Poland and Yugoslavia began in the 1970s with
the sharp rise in interest rates soon after these countries had
accepted offers of substantial loans from Western financial institutions.
A similar impact occurred in third world countries, where national
liberation movements had gained power despite the best efforts
of the United States and had borrowed on the international market
for the purpose of underwriting much- needed new infrastructure.
These economies were to be plunged in a crippling debt crisis
following the rise of interest rates from 3 percent to 30 percent
in a few short years. In fact, they have never quite recovered
since.
As with rising oil prices, so it was with
burgeoning interest rates: the U.S. economy (although hit hard
by the recession brought on by the rising prices of oil and money)
improved its relative financial position, compared not only with
Europe and Japan but also with the third world and the Communist
nations. By the early 1980s, under the Reagan administration,
U.S. policy fully endorsed this new reality and a consensus emerged
that the balance of payments ought not to be the focus of attention
anymore; that what mattered was the strength of U.S. finance,
founded on the strength of its multinationals, particularly in
the energy sector, and on the ability to make the dollar accepted
internationally (without any form of concrete payment behind it).
In simpler, albeit more emotive, terms,
the era that began in the early 1980s is marked by the transformation
of the world economy into a periphery from which the United States
imports huge quantities of goods with little concern for its balance
of payments.
p84
The United States pays for its deficit to the rest of the world
by issuing bonds and treasury bills or by attracting capital through
its stock exchanges. Low U.S. inflation is pivotal to this strategy.
For unless inflation is kept at close to 1 or 2 percent, the capacity
of the U.S. economy to attract capital would be undermined. This
is because, if there is relatively high inflation, the asset values
and financial assets purchased by incoming capital will decline
in value. So from the early 1980s onwards, the main game in Washington
was reinforcing U.S. financial capital through the creation of
a highly deflationary international environment.
By extension, the rest of the world supplies
the United States with commodities at noninflationary prices and,
meanwhile, the United States (unlike every other country, including
Europe and Japan) does not have to deal with its deficit. This
is very similar to the situation that Britain established in relation
to India. From the end of the nineteenth century until the Great
War, Britain ran a huge balance-of-payments deficit. It managed
to maintain it by having India export to the rest of the world
and by taxing away, in one way or another, the surplus that India
generated through its exports. These capital flows and taxes made
it back to the City of London, thus clearing the deficit. This
is the model that the United States has been emulating in the
last twenty years. Instead, however, of using a single country
(as Britain had Lone), the United States has applied it to the
rest of the world.
p85
The drive to dollarize whole foreign economies, especially in
Latin America, is to be understood as part of the same mind set.
Dollarization means that the U.S. dollar becomes the country's
de facto local currency. The main effect of this move, from the
U.S. perspective, is that the demand for dollars then depends
not only on the international transactions of other countries
but on the domestic transactions of the dollarized economies as
well. This gives the United States added political leverage and
reduces further the preoccupation with external debt. The reason
is simple: as the demand for dollars by foreigners for their own
domestic purposes increases, the U.S. balance of payments plays
a decreasing role in shaping the dollar's value in the international
money markets.
p85
The capacity of the United States to pursue its post-Vietnam global
design depends on its capacity to maintain a steady flow of capital
from the rest of the world. This capacity, in turn, hinges crucially
on its political dominance over the rest of the world. Two analysts
foreshadowed this when they wrote in 1986, "Even as military
assistance and arms sales rocketed upward in the 1970s, many American
business figures pressed for an enhanced American capacity for
direct intervention abroad."
Anyone who read Bush administration adviser
Richard Perle's 1996 report to Israel's then prime minister-elect
Netanyahu, "A Clean Break: A New Strategy for Securing the
Realm," will immediately recognize the author's emphasis
on the nexus between geostrategic concerns and the imperative
to secure privileged access to oil. Even if the United States
did not need a monopoly over Middle Eastern and Central Asian
oil for itself, it would wish to control it in order to guarantee
its financial centers a steady flow of petrodollars.
In an ironic sense, the latest war in
Iraq might not be about the oil per se. It is about ensuring that
whoever controls it buys and sells it in U.S. dollars through
the New York commodities exchange. For it is this flow of finance,
and to a much lesser extent the ownership of oil, which enables
the United States to continue its policy of world dominance through
an unbounded balance of payments. Of course, the fact that the
oil would be taken over in the post-Saddam era by Bush and his
Texan friends does not reduce the administration's enthusiasm.
In November 2000, Richard N. Haass, then
director of policy planning in the State Department, strengthened
our argument by writing an essay advocating that the United States
adopt an "imperial" foreign policy. He defined this
as "a foreign policy that attempts to organize the world
along certain principles affecting relations between states and
conditions within them." This would not be achieved through
colonies but through what he termed "informal control,"
using military might if necessary. Global mechanisms such as international
financial markets, the WTO, and the IMF were essential devices
for ensuring the dominance of U.S. interests, with the military
iron fist backing up the invisible hand of the market.
p87
For the last year or so, circles in Washington have been promoting
the view that global warming might be bad for most parts of the
world but not necessarily bad for the United States. There is,
indeed, speculation that U.S. agribusiness will benefit from an
increase in global temperatures because, according to estimates
based on large-scale computer simulations, the productivity of
American agriculture will rise as long as genetically modified
seeds are utilized extensively. Meanwhile, with a declining world
food production, U.S. "comparative advantage" is predicted
to strengthen. Once more, the United States appears to the rest
of the world as completely obsessed with the project of remaining
unimpeded by its balance-of-trade deficit, even at the planet's
expense.
The New Design seems to revolve around
the axis of control over energy sources, as well as environmental
change, with an explicit view to enhancing the U.S. capacity to
draw capital flows from the rest of the world and thus avoid domestic
crises due to the growing indebtedness of U.S. families arid businesses.
If the New Design requires global military campaigns and the alienation
of world opinion on matters of global importance (e.g., the environment,
world peace), this is deemed a small price to pay for a huge and
steady windfall.
p88
... there is a rapidly growing division in the U.S. economy between
a sector connected to the aeronautic-computer-electronics (ACE)
military-industrial complex and the rest of the U.S. economy.
Interestingly, although the comparative productivity and competitiveness
of the ACE-linked sector is rising vis-à-vis the European
and Japanese economies, the rest of the U.S. economy is falling
behind. Moreover, the ACE sector is severing its links with the
latter, increasing the inequality in jobs, incomes, and opportunities.
Put simply, the latest U.S. economic miracle has nothing to do
with the flexibility of its labor markets and the entrepreneurship
of the average American; it is a direct product of industries
that grew out of its global geostrategic hegemony... the beneficiaries
of this strategy? One thing we know for sure is that the beneficiaries
are not average Americans. In fact, never before have so few Americans
had so much while J e many had to survive on so little. ... the
beneficiaries are three sectors of the U.S. economy: energy multinationals
(mostly oil companies), the financial institutions handling the
capital flows from the rest of the world, and the ACE industries
hooked into the U.S. military.
p89
... the United States re-created a nation with a political apparatus
entirely new to it. The loose two-party state imposed by the United
States, and effectively written into Japan's constitution, was
designed to prevent politicians from having any significant influence
on policy. The Japanese bureaucracy is powerful, largely efficient,
and autonomous. Thus the people of Japan have become the last
Japanese colony, ruled over by a class of bureaucratic entrepreneurs
without political ambitions. Though this model provides stability
and conformity and is conducive to speedy economic development
at times when demand from the United States is high, it is utterly
incapable of initiating change, of giving voice to the political
aspirations of the Japanese masses, or even ~f mapping out an
autonomous Japanese trade or finance policy.
Examples of Japan's lack of autonomy abound.
The United States ha ensured that, following the rise of the Southeast
Asian tigers, Japan would be selling technological or capital
goods to Korea, Malaysia, and Thailand, usually through the transfer
of superseded production lines. Interestingly, most regional trade
was bilateral (as opposed to trilateral): Southeast Asia was trading
directly with the United States and so was Japan. By contrast,
the flow of final goods between Southeast Asia and Japan was minuscule.
In other words, the United States prevented Japan from establishing
an economic zone around it similar to that enjoyed by Germany
in the euro zone.
When, following the 1997 crises, Japanese
officials realized the benefits lost due to their failure properly
to integrate Southeast Asia into the Japanese economy, they tried
to make amends. Alas, the United States denied Japan the instruments
as well as the opportunities to alter the situation substantially.
With the world economy, excluding the United States, in permanent
deflation, Japanese factories have no means of making use of their
huge capacity, and thus the Japanese economy finds it impossible
to transcend a state of perpetual recession.
This makes Japan even more dependent on
exporting to the United States. U.S. officials allow Japanese
firms access to American consumers but at a hefty price: Japan
must forego any plans of becoming a foreign capital importer in
competition with the United States. In practical terms, it is
forbidden from developing its own international financial policy
or from establishing new international bodies for the minimization
of financial volatility-especially in Southeast Asia. It is therefore
wholly unsurprising that Japanese politicians are not speak out
against U.S. policy at any significant level.
p91
European policy makers in Brussels, and their Japanese counterparts
in Tokyo, waste countless trees writing and distributing research
papers on entrepreneurship and competitiveness, desperately seeking
ways of playing catch up with the United States. The most recent
such literature from Brussels seems to assume that the U.S. economy
is more energetic than those of Europe and Japan because of the
superiority of the Protestant ethic, the debilitating effects
on incentives caused by overgenerous safety nets, and overly regulated
labor markets. The problem with this assumption is that it is
at odds with any logically coherent analysis of the global political
economy.
... The only sectors in which the Americans
have overtaken the Europeans and Japanese are those which are
intimately linked to the U.S. defense budget-a whopping powerhouse
that makes European alleged statism seem like a children's fancy
dress party.
p92
U.S. growth in the 1990s was financed by borrowing, so much borrowing
from overseas that in the last few years, if all Americans were
to sell everything they own, they would still not be able to repay
their loans.
Pox Americana
Home
Page