Japan and the Economics
of the American Empire
excerpted from the book
Blowback
The Costs and Consequences of American Empire
by Chalmers Johnson
Henry Holt, 2000
p177
From approximately 1950 to 1975, the United States treated Japan
a beloved ward, indulging its every economic need and proudly
patronizing it as a star capitalist pupil. The United States sponsored
Japan's entry into many international institutions, like the United
Nations and the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development,
well before a post-World War 11 global consensus in favor of Japan
had developed. It also transferred crucial technologies to the
Japanese on virtually concessionary terms and opened its markets
to Japanese products while tolerating Japan's protection of its
own domestic market. It even supported the Japanese side in all
claims by individual American firms that they had been damaged
by Japanese competitors. In addition, the United States allowed
Japan to retain an artificially undervalued currency in order
to give its exports a price advantage for well over a decade longer
than it did any of the rebuilt European economies.
We proclaimed Japan a democracy and a model of what free markets
could achieve while simultaneously helping to rig both its economic
and political systems. We used the CIA to finance the ruling party
and engaged in all manner of dirty tricks to divide and discredit
domestic socialists. In this process there was much self-deception.
For far too long. America's leading officials insisted that Japan
could never be an economic competitor of the United States'. President
Eisenhower's secretary of state John Foster Dulles was, for example,
convinced that while the Japanese might be able to sell shirts,
pajamas, "and perhaps cocktail napkins" to the American
market, little else was possible for them. Americans did not wake
up to Japan's competitive challenge until their steel, consumer
electronics, robotics, automotive, camera, and semiconductor industries
were virtually extinct or fighting for their lives.
p180
... the ideological challenge to the Soviet Union was the development
and propagation of an American economic ideology that might counter
the promise of Marxism-what today we call "neoclassical economics,"
which has gained an intellectual status in American economic activities
and governmental affairs similar to that of Marxism-Leninism in
the former USSR. Needless to say, Soviet citizens never understood
Marxism-Leninism as an ideology until after it had collapsed,
just as Americans like to think (or pretend) that their economics
is a branch of science, not a fighting doctrine to defend and
advance their interests against those of others. They may consider
most economists to be untrustworthy witch doctors, but they regard
the tenets of a laissez-faire economy-with its cutthroat competition,
casino stock exchange, massive inequalities of wealth, and a minor,
regulatory role for government-as self-evident truths.
Until the late 1950s, academic economics remained one of the
social sciences, like anthropology, sociology, and political science-a
non-experimental, often speculative investigation into the ways
individuals, families, firms, markets, industries, and national
economies behaved under different conditions and influences. It
was concerned with full employment, price stability, growth, public
finance, labor relations, and similar socioeconomic subjects.
After it became the chief ideological counterweight to Marxism-Leninism
during the Cold War, its practitioners tried to extract it from
the social sciences and re-create it as a hard science.
Its propositions were now expressed less in words than in
simultaneous equations, the old ideas of Adam Smith reappearing
as fully mathematized axioms, increasingly divorced from empirical
research. Its data were said to be "stylized facts,"
and economists set out to demonstrate through deductive reasoning
expressed in mathematical formulas that resources could be allocated
efficiently only through an unfettered market. By now all these
terms ("resources," "efficiency," "markets")
had been transformed into abstractions, not unlike the abstract
formulations ("the proletariat," "the bourgeoisie,"
"class conflict") of its Soviet opponents. English-speaking
economics became such a "hard science" that in 1969
_ the central bank of Sweden started giving Nobel Prizes to its
adepts, virtually all of them American academicians. This ensured
that virtually all aspiring economists would in the future try
to do so-called theoretical economics-that is, the algebraic modeling
of markets-rather than old-fashioned empirical and inductive research
into real-world economies.
Economics split from the social sciences and took up a new
position somewhere close to mathematics. Economists were now endlessly
called upon by governmental bodies to testify that the American
economy was unmatchable, even if it sometimes behaved badly because
of overspending liberals, pork-barrel politics, or greedy monopolists.
Alternatives to it were understood to be either converging with
it or destined to fail. Economics no longer studied the economy;
it spoke ex cathedra about what was orthodox and what was heresy.
Meanwhile, empirical research on economic phenomena migrated to
business schools, commercial think tanks, and the other social
sciences.
Unquestionably, after the first two decades of the Cold War,
in purely dichotomous choice between an economy based on Marxism-Leninism
and one based on free-market capitalism-as exemplified by the
economies of the Soviet Union and the United States-most people
around the world would have chosen the free market. But in East
Asia, at the height of the Sino-Soviet dispute and the American
war in Vietnam, neither ideology was working out according to
either superpower's script. The Chinese were discrediting forever
whatever attractiveness might have remained in the forced-draft
economic achievements of the Soviet model. Through bungling, megalomania,
and deep ideological confusion about what Marxism and the Soviet
experience taught, the Chinese Communist Party managed to kill
thirty million of its own citizens and then, in a paroxysm of
mutual blame, came close to destroying its unmatchable cultural
legacy in the so-called Cultural Revolution. Today this period
is recognized-even in China-as a monumental disaster, but at the
time many Americans, from idealistic leftist students to presidents
and other political leaders, failing to understand what was happening,
retained a sentimental attraction to Mao Zedong and Zhou Enlai,
the mismanagers of the Chinese revolution.
The truly surprising development in East Asia, however, was
that America's "non-Communist" satellites, protectorates,
and dependencies were starting to get rich and to compete with
their superpower benefactor. All of this was camouflaged by the
Cold War itself, so that the enrichment of East Asia occurred
almost surreptitiously. The year-in, year-out record-breaking
growth rates of such previously poor places as Japan, South Korea,
and Taiwan were not precisely what American elites had expected,
but they were explained away as nothing more than confirmations-even
overconfirmations-of officially espoused free-market ideology
and so were greeted with parental pride.
If the capitalist economies of East Asia were starting to
perform better than the United States itself, this anomaly was
usually attributed to mysterious Japanese or Asian cultural or
even spiritual factors or to complacency on the part of American
managers and workers. By the time the Western world awoke to what
had actually happened, economic growth in East Asia was self-sustaining
and unstoppable by external actions (although many Asians thought
this was exactly what the United States was attempting when its
policies toward the area led to the meltdown of 1997). The enrichment
of East Asia under the cover of the Cold War was surely the most
important, least analyzed development in world politics during
the second half of the twentieth century. It remains to this day
intellectually indigestible in the United States.
The fundamental problem is not simply that in the Cold War
e~ Japan attained a $5 trillion economy-although that alone was
an unexpected competitive challenge to American economic preeminence-but
how it did so. It had found a third way between the socialist
displacement of the market advocated by Soviet theorists and an
uncritical reliance on the market advocated by American theorists.
The Japanese had invented a different kind of capitalism-something
no defender of the American empire could accept. It was therefore
assumed either that the Japanese were cheating (and all that we
needed to compete successfully against them was a "level
playing field") or that they must be headed for a collapse
similar to the one that had overtaken the USSR.
In turning neo-classical economic theory into a fighting ideology,
American ideologues encountered one element of capitalist thought
that they could not express in abstract, seemingly "scientific"
mathematical terms. This was the set of institutions through which
competitive market relationships actually produce their benefits.
Institutions are the concrete, more-or-less enduring relationships
through which people work, save, invest, and earn a living-such
things as stock exchanges, banks, labor unions, corporations,
safety nets, families, inheritance rules, and tax systems. This
is the realm of the legal, political, and social order, where
many considerations that govern the economy other than efficiency
contend for primacy. For economic theorists institutions are "black
boxes," entities that receive and transmit economic stimuli
but are themselves unaffected by economic theory.
In attempting to forge a fully numerical, scientific-looking
model of the capitalist economy for purposes of the Cold War,
Western ideologues simply assumed that the institutions of modem
capitalism must be those that existed in the United States in
the late Eisenhower era. This meant that savings were typically
moved from the saver to industry through a capital market (such
as the New York Stock Exchange) rather than, for example, through
the banking system. They assumed that industrial-labor conflicts
were settled by interminable strikes, and not by, for example,
offering some workers career job security; and they assumed that
the whole purpose of an economy was to serve the short term interests
of consumers, instead of some overarching goal such as the wealth
and power of the nation as a whole.
These American assumptions were almost identical to the Soviet
assumption that the institutions of "socialism" must
be those that existed in the USSR during, say, the Khrushchev
era. Neither side ever produced an ideological model to sell to
others that could be divorced from their own country. Because
of this inability to express the institutions of either socialism
or capitalism in some culturally neutral-or at least more varied-way,
it is understandable that many observers simply reduced the claims
of Marxist-Leninist ideology to the USSR and those of free-market
capitalism to the United States.
In finding a third way, Japan's postwar economic "miracle"
reinvented not economic theory but the institutions of modem capitalism
so that they would produce utterly different outcomes from those
imagined in the American model. Given Japan's history of catch-up
industrialization, its overarching need to avoid the victimization
and colonialism to which every other area of East Asia had succumbed,
its virtual dearth of raw materials, its dependence on manufacturing
and international trade to sustain its large population, and its
overwhelming defeat in World War 11, it could not ever have become
a clone of the United States. Its postwar planners and technocrats
instead organized a capitalist economy intended to serve the interests
of producers over consumers. They forced Japan's citizens to save
by providing little in the way of a safety net; they encouraged
labor harmony regardless of what it did to individual rights;
and they built industries based on the highest possible human
input rather than simply on some naturally given comparative advantage,
such as cheap labor or proximity to a large market like China's.
Their goal was to enrich Japan, if not necessarily the Japanese
themselves. They viewed all economic transactions as strategic:
theirs was to be an economy organized for war but now directed
toward ostensibly peaceful competition with other countries.
p189
... most Americans failed to grasp how crucially Japan's industrial
policy depended on its political and military relationship with
the United States and on access to its vast market. Nor did they
understand that the Japanese were investing the huge trade profits
in American Treasury securities that were, in turn, helping to
finance America's huge debts and making the American financial
system critically dependent on Japanese savings. This growing
dependency made American officials reluctant to criticize the
Japanese in any way. Even when they did so, the Japanese rationalized
such criticism as meant only for U.S. domestic consumption.
What Americans, including the revisionists, failed to see
was that the Japanese economy, still devoted to exporting a vast
array of ever more sophisticated and technologically advanced
manufactured goods primarily to the American market, was generating
an industrial overcapacity that would eventually threaten the
health of the world economy. Moreover, as much of Asia began to
emulate the Japanese form of capitalism or become offshore manufacturing
platforms for Japanese corporations, this overcapacity threatened
to reach crisis proportions. The crisis came to a head in 1997
and has been a continuing feature of the international economy
I ever since.
p192
As the Cold War receded into history, the United States, rather
than dissolving its Cold War arrangements, insisted on strengthening
them as part of a renewed commitment to global hegemony. Japan
was supposed to remain a satellite of the United States, whether
anyone dared use that term or not. Meanwhile, annual American
trade deficits with Japan soared. American manufacturing continued
to be hollowed out, while a vast manufacturing overcapacity was
generated in Japan and its Southeast Asian subsidiaries. Capital
transfers from Japan to the United States generated huge gains
for financiers and produced an illusion of prosperity in the United
States, but in 1997, it all started to unravel. The most severe
economic crisis since the Great Depression hit the East Asian
economies and began to spread around the world.
Blowback
- The Costs and Consequences of American Empire
U.S.
Foreign Policy
Index
of Website
Home
Page