Meltdown
excerpted from the book
Blowback
The Costs and Consequences of American Empire
by Chalmers Johnson
Henry Holt, 2000
p193
The global economic crisis that began in Thailand in July 1997
had two causes. First, the built-in contradictions of the American
satellite system in East Asia had heightened to such a degree
that the system itself unexpectedly began to splinter and threatened
to blow apart. Second, the United States, relieved of the prudence
imposed on it by the Cold War, when any American misstep was chalked
up as a Soviet gain, launched a campaign to force the rest of
the world to adopt its form of capitalism. This effort went under
the rubric of "globalization." As these two complex
undertakings-perpetuating Cold War structures after they had lost
their purpose and trying to "globalize" countries that
thought they had invented a different kind of capitalism-played
themselves out around the world, they threatened a worldwide collapse
of demand and a new depression. Whatever happens, the crisis probably
signaled the beginning of the end of the American empire and a
shift to a tripolar world in which the United States, Europe,
and East Asia simultaneously share power and compete for it.
p194
... capitalist states enforce an inherently discriminatory division
of labor on less developed countries by selling them manufactured
goods and buying from them only raw materials, an extremely profitable
arrangement for capitalists in advanced countries and one that
certainly keeps underdeveloped countries underdeveloped. This
is why revolutionary movements in underdeveloped countries want
either to overthrow the capitalist order or to industrialize their
economies as fast as possible.
Such economic colonialism has long existed in many aspects
of America's relations with Latin America. During the Cold War,
the United States wrapped this system of dependency in the rhetoric
of anticommunism, labeling elected leaders Communists if they
seemed to endanger American corporate interests, as in Guatemala
in 1954, and ordering the CIA to overthrow them. Campaigns against
the influence of Fidel Castro, for instance, often proved of great
usefulness to American companies south of the border...
p195
... the "newly industrialized countries" of South Korea,
Taiwan, Hong Kong, and Singapore; then, the late developers of
Southeast Asia, Malaysia, Indonesia, Thailand, and the Philippines;
and finally, China, at present the world's fastest-growing economy.
p195
Judith Stein, a professor of history at the City College of New
York, has detailed how the de facto U.S. industrial policy of
sacrificing American workers to pay for its empire devastated
African-American households in Birmingham, Alabama, and Pittsburgh,
Pennsylvania. This is, of course, but another form of blowback.
She writes, "At the outset of the Cold War, reconstructing
or creating steel industries abroad was a keystone of U.S. strategic
policy, and encouraging steel imports became a tool for maintaining
vital alliances. The nation's leaders by and large ignored the
resulting conflict between Cold War and domestic goals. Reminiscing
about elite thinking in that era, former Federal Reserve Board
chairman Paul A. Volcker recalled that 'the strength and prosperity
of the American economy was too evident to engender concern about
the costs.' Moreover, American economic ideologues always dominated
what debate there was, couching the problem in terms of protectionism
versus internationalism, never in terms of prosperity for whites
versus poverty for blacks. The true costs to the United States
should be measured in terms of crime statistics, ruined inner
cities, and rug addiction, as well as trade deficits.
p196
To base a capitalist economy mainly on export sales rather than
domestic demand, however, ultimately subverts the function of
the unfettered world market to reconcile and bring into balance
supply and demand. Instead of producing what the people of a particular
economy can actually use, East Asian export regimes thrived on
foreign demand artificially engineered by an imperialist power.
In East Asia during the Cold War, the strategy worked so long
as the American economy remained overwhelmingly larger than the
economies of its dependencies and so long as only Japan and perhaps
one or two smaller countries pursued this strategy. But by the
1980s the Japanese economy had become twice the size of both Germanies.
Anything it did affected not just the American but the global
economy. Moreover, virtually everyone else in East Asia (and potentially
every underdeveloped country on earth) had some knowledge of how
to create such a miracle economy and many were trying to duplicate
Japanese-style high-speed growth. An overcapacity for products
oriented to the American market (or products needed to further
expand export-oriented economies) became overwhelming. There were
too many factories turning out athletic shoes, automobiles, television
sets, semiconductors, petrochemicals, steel, and l ships for too
few buyers.
p197
This is not to say that all the barefoot peoples of the world
who might like to wear athletic shoes or all the relatively poor
people who might someday be able to afford a television set or
an automobile are satisfied. But for now they are too poor to
be customers. The current overcapacity in East Asia has created
intense competition among American and European multinational
corporations. Their answer has been to lower costs by moving as
much of their manufacturing as possible to places where skilled
workers are paid very little. These poorly paid workers in places
like Vietnam, Indonesia, and China cannot consume what they produce,
while middle- and lower-class consumers back in the United States
and Europe cannot buy much more either because their markets are
saturated or their incomes are stagnant or falling. The underlying
danger is a structural collapse of demand leading to recession
and ultimately to something like the Great Depression. As the
economic journalist William Greider has put it in his book One
World, Ready or Not, "Shipping high-wage jobs to low-wage
economies has obvious, immediate economic benefits. But, roughly
speaking, it also replaces high-wage consumers with low-wage ones.
That exchange is debilitating for the entire system." The
only answer is to create new demand by paying poor people more
for their work. But the political authorities capable of enacting
and enforcing rules to enlarge demand could not do so even if
they wanted to because "globalization" has placed the
matter beyond their control.
A crisis of oversupply was inevitable given the passage of
time and the unwillingness of imperial America to reform its system
of satellites. Even in the late 1990s, the American economy continued
to serve as the consumer of last resort for the enormous manufacturing
capacity of all of East Asia, although doing so produced trade
deficits that cumulatively transferred trillions of dollars from
the United States to Asia. This caused an actual decline in the
household incomes of the bottom tenth of American families, whose
real incomes fell by 13 percent between 1973 and 1995. It was
only in 1997 that a weak link snapped- not, ironically, in trade,
but finance-and threatened to bring the system down.
The financial systems of all the high-growth East Asian economies
were based on encouraging exceptionally high domestic household
savings as the main source of capital for industrial growth. Such
savings were achieved by discouraging consumption through the
high domestic pricing of consumer goods (which, of course, also
led to charges of "dumping" of normally priced goods
when they were sent abroad). To save in such a context was a patriotic
act, but it was also a matter of survival in societies that provided
little in the way of a social safety net for times of emergencies,
and in which housing often had to be bought outright or in which
interest payments on mortgages was not treated favorably as a
tax deduction.
East Asian governments collected these savings in banks affiliated
with industrial combines or in government savings institutions
such as post offices. In organizing their economies, they had
chosen not to rely primarily on stock exchanges to raise the capital
their export industries needed. Instead they found it much more
effective to guide the investment of the savings in these banks
to the industries the governments wanted to develop. In East Asia,
ostensibly private banks thus became partners in business enterprises
and industrial groups, not independent creditors concerned first
and foremost with the profitability of a company or the success
of a loan. These banks in effect followed government orders and
felt secure so long as they did so.
p199
Until very recently Japanese corporations were "owned"
entirely by one another in elaborate cross-share-holding deals
designed to keep people like Pickens out and to keep the enterprise
working for the country rather than for the profits of shareholders.
The sale of shares was not a way to raise capital, and the people
who held them were uninterested in the risks or profits that the
company's operations entailed.
This was actually a brilliant system. Oxfam, the British development
and relief agency, maintains that the Cold War East Asian economies
achieved "the fastest reduction in poverty for the greatest
number of people in history." But the stability of any East
Asian economy depended on its keeping its financial system closed-that
is, under national control and supervision. Once opened up to
the rest of the world, the financial structures of the East Asian
developmental states were extremely vulnerable to attack by foreign
capital and international financial speculators. The industrial
policy system produced corporations in which the burden of debt
was five times greater than the value of the shareholders' investments,
whereas these so-called debt-to-equity ratios for U.S. firms are
less than one to one. East Asian corporations operating with such
large burdens of debt were normally indifferent to the price of
their equity shares. Instead, they serviced these debts at their
banks with income from foreign sales. When they were unable to
repay their loans, the banks themselves very quickly veered toward
bankruptcy. The whole system depended on continuous growth of
revenue from export sales.
p200
Then, without warning, that order changed. Perhaps the first important
blow to the East Asian model of capitalism came in 1971, when
President Nixon abolished the Bretton Woods system of fixed exchange
rates, created by the United Nations Monetary and Financial Conference
in the summer of 1944 at Bretton Woods, New Hampshire. The treaties
that resulted from Bretton Woods were the most important efforts
of the victorious Allies of World War 11 to create a better global
financial system than the one that existed in the 1930s. The Allies
intended to prevent a recurrence of the protectionism and competitive
devaluations of national currencies that had deepened the Great
Depression and fueled the rise of Nazism. To do these things,
the Bretton Woods conference established a system of fixed exchange
rates among the world's currencies. It also created the International
Monetary Fund, to help countries whose economic conditions forced
them to alter the value of their currencies, and the World Bank,
to help finance postwar rebuilding. The value of every currency
was tied to the value of the U.S. dollar, which was in turn backed
by the U.S. govemment's guarantee that it would convert dollars
into gold on demand.
Nixon decided to end the Bretton Woods system because the
Vietnam War had imposed such excessive expenditures on the United
States that ( it was hemorrhaging money. He concluded that the
government could no longer afford to exchange its currency for
a fixed value of gold. A more effective answer would have been
to end the Vietnam War and balance the federal budget. Instead,
what actually occurred was that the dollar and other currencies
were allowed to "float"-that is, to be converted into
other currencies at whatever rate the market determined.
The historian, business executive, and novelist John Ralston
Saul described Nixon's action as "perhaps the single most
destructive act of the postwar world. The West was returned to
the monetary barbarism and instability of the l9th century."
Floating exchange rates introduced a major element of instability
into the international trading system. They stimulated the growth
of so-called finance capitalism- which refers to making money
from trading stocks, bonds, currencies, and other forms of securities
as well as lending money to companies, governments, and consumers
rather than manufacturing products and selling them at prices
determined by unfettered markets. Finance capitalism, as its name
implies, means making money by manipulating money, not trying
to achieve a balance between the producers and consumers of goods.
On the contrary, finance capitalism aggravates the problems of
equilibrium within and among capitalist economies in order to
profit from the discrepancies. During the nineteenth century the
appearance, and then dominance, of finance capitalism was widely
recognized as a defect of improperly regulated capitalist systems.
Theorists from Adam Smith to John Hobson observed that capitalists
do not really like being capitalists. They would much rather be
monopolists, rentiers, inside traders, or usurers or in some other
way achieve an unfair advantage that might allow them to profit
more easily from the mental and physical work of others. Smith
and Hobson both believed that finance capitalism produced the
pathologies of the global economy they called mercantilism and
imperialism: that is, true economic exploitation of others rather
than mutually beneficial exchanges among economic actors.
Opponents of capitalism, such as Marxists, viewed such problems
as inescapable and the ultimate reason capitalist systems must
sooner or later implode. Supporters of capitalism, such as Smith
and Hobson, thought that its problems could be solved by imposing
social controls on the monetary system, as did the Bretton Woods
agreement. As they saw it, lack of such controls led to the maldistribution
of purchasing power. Too few rich people and too many poor people
resulted in an insufficient demand for goods and services. The
"excess capital" thus generated had to find some place
to go. In the maturing capitalist countries of the nineteenth
century, financiers pressured their governments to create colonies
in which they could invest and obtain profits of a sort no longer
available to them at home. The nineteenth-century theorists believed
this was the root cause of imperialism and that its specific antidote
was the use of state power to raise the ability of the domestic
public to consume. After the United States ended the Bretton Woods
system, these kinds of problems once again returned to haunt the
world.
In the 1980s, when Japanese trade with the United States began
seriously to damage the American economy, the leaders of both
countries chose to deal with the problem by manipulating exchange
rates. This could be done by having the central banks of each
country work in concert buying and selling dollars and yen. In
a meeting of finance ministers at the Plaza Hotel in New York
City in 1985, the United States and Japan agreed in the Plaza
Accord to force down the value of the dollar and force up the
value of the yen, thereby making American products cheaper on
international markets and Japanese goods more expensive. The low
(that is, inexpensive) dollar lasted for a decade.
The Plaza Accord was intended to ameliorate the United States'
huge trade deficits with Japan, but altering exchange rates affects
only prices, and price competitiveness and price advantages were
not the cause of the deficits. The accord was based on good classroom
economic theory, but it ignored the realities of how the Japanese
economy was actually organized and its dependence on sales to
the American market. The accord was, as a result, the root cause
of the major catastrophes that befell East Asia's economies over
the succeeding fifteen years.
Once the high yen-low dollar regime was in place, the U.S.
government assumed that the trade imbalance would correct itself.
The United States did nothing to end Japan's barriers against
imports and still permitted Japan to export into its market anything
and everything it could sell there. Japan reacted to the high
yen by putting its industrial policy system into high gear in
order to lower costs so it could continue its export-led growth,
even at a disadvantageously high exchange rate. The Japanese Ministry
of Finance also lowered domestic interest rates to make capital
virtually free and encouraged industrial groups to invest more
vigorously than they had ever done before. The result was fantastic
industrial overcapacity and a "bubble economy," in which
the prices of such things as real estate lost any relationship
to underlying values. Business leaders proudly announced on American
television that a square meter of the Ginza was worth more than
all of Seattle. Ultimately, huge debts accumulated and the Japanese
banks were stuck with at least $600 billion in "non-performing"
loans that threatened to bankrupt the entire banking system.
By 1995, the contradictions were starting to come to a head.
Japan still had a huge surplus of savings, which it exported to
the United States by investing in U.S. Treasury bonds, thereby
helping fund America's debts and keep its domestic interest rates
low. And yet Japan itself was simultaneously facing the possibility
of the collapse of several of its bankrupt banks. Financial leaders
said to the Americans that they needed relief from the high yen
in order to increase Japan's exports. They hoped to solve their
problems in the traditional way, via more export-led growth. Eisuke
Sakakibara, then Japan's vice minister for international affairs
in the Ministry of Finance, readily acknowledges that he intervened
with Washington to lower the value of the yen and admits to his
"inadvertent role in precipitating one of the 20th century's
greatest economic crises. The United States went along with this;
facing reelection in 1996, Bill Clinton certainly did not want
Japanese capital called home to prop up Japanese banks at that
moment. As a result, between 1995 and 1997 the U.S. Treasury and
the Bank of Japan engineered a "reverse Plaza Accord"-which
led to a 60 percent fall of the yen against the dollar.
However, in the wake of the Plaza Accord, many newly developing
Southeast Asian economies had by then "pegged" their
currencies to the low dollar, establishing official rates at which
businesses and countries around the world could exchange Southeast
Asian currencies for dollars. So long as the dollar remained cheap,
this gave them a price advantage over competitors, including Japan,
and made the region very attractive to foreign investors because
of its rapidly expanding exports. It also encouraged reckless
lending by domestic banks, since pegged exchange rates seemed
to protect them from the unpredictability of currency fluctuations.
During the early l990s, all of the East Asian countries other
than Japan grew at explosive rates. Then the "reverse Plaza
Accord" brought disaster. Suddenly, their exports became
far more expensive than Japan's. Export growth in second-tier
countries like South Korea, Thailand, Indonesia, Malaysia, and
the Philippines went from 30 percent a year in early 1995 to zero
by mid-1996.
Certain developments in the advanced industrial democracies
only compounded these problems. Some of their capitalists had
spent the post-Plaza Accord decade developing "financial
instruments" that enabled them to bet on whether global currencies
would rise or fall. They had also accumulated huge pools of capital,
partly because aging populations led to the exceptional growth
of pension funds, which had to be invested somewhere. Mutual funds
within the United States alone grew from about $1 trillion in
the early 1980s to $4.5 trillion by the mid-l990s. These massive
pools of capital could have catastrophic effects on the value
of a foreign currency if transferred in and then suddenly out
of a target country. Fast-developing computer and telecommunications
technologies radically lowered transaction costs while increasing
the speed and precision with which finance capitalists could transfer
money and manipulate currencies on a global scale. The managers
who con
trolled these funds began to encourage investment anywhere
on earth under the rubric of "globalization," an esoteric
term for what in the nineteenth century was simply called imperialism.
They argued that excess capital should be allowed to flow freely
in and out of any and all countries. Some economists argued that
the free flow of capital was the same thing as the free flow of
goods, despite mountainous evidence to the contrary.
With hegemony established on military terms and the American
public more or less unaware of what its government was doing,
government officials, economic theorists, and members of the Wall
Street-Treasury complex launched an astonishingly ambitious, even
megalomaniacal attempt to make the rest of the world adopt American
economic institutions and norms. One could argue that the project
reflected the last great expression of eighteenth-century Enlightenment
rationalism, as idealistic and utopian as the paradise of pure
communism that Marx envisioned; or one could conclude that having
defeated the Fascists and the Communists, the United States now
sought to defeat its last remaining rivals for global dominance:
the nations of East Asia that had used the conditions of the Cold
War to enrich themselves. In the latter view, U.S. interests lay
not in globalization but in bringing increasingly self-confident
competitors to their knees.
In any event, buoyed by what the apologist for America Francis
Fukuyama has called the "end of history"-the belief
that with the end of the Cold War all alternatives to the American
economic system had been discredited-American leaders became hubristic.
Although there is no evidence that Washington hatched a conspiracy
to extend the scope of its global hegemony, a sense of moral superiority
on the part of some and of opportunism on the part of others more
than sufficed to create a similar effect.
The shock that brought this edifice crashing to the ground
started the summer of 1997, when some foreign financiers discovered
that they had lent huge sums to companies in East Asia with unimaginably
large debts and, by Western standards, very low levels of shareholder
investment. They feared that other lenders, particularly the hedge
funds, would make or had already made the same discovery. They
knew that if all of them started to reduce their risks, the aggregate
effect would be to force local governments to de-peg their currencies
from the dollar and devalue them. Since this would raise the loan
burdens of even the most expertly managed companies, they too
would have to rush to buy dollars before the price went out of
sight, thereby helping to drive the value of any domestic currency
even lower.
The countries that had followed recent American economic advice
most closely were most seriously devastated.
p210
The International Monetary Fund entered this picture and turned
a financial panic into a crisis of the underlying economic systems.
As already mentioned, the Bretton Woods conference of 1944 had
created the IMF to service the system of fixed exchange rates
that lasted until the "Nixon shocks" of 1971. It survived
its loss of mission in 1971 to become, in the economist Robert
Kuttner's words, "the premier instrument of deflation, as
well as the most powerful unaccountable institution in the world.''
The IMF is essentially a covert arm of the U.S. Treasury, yet
beyond congressional oversight because it is formally an international
organization. Its voting rules ensure that it is dominated by
the United States and its allies. India and China have fewer votes
in the IMF, for example, than the Netherlands. As the prominent
Harvard economist Jeffrey Sachs puts its, "Not unlike the
days when the British Empire placed senior officials directly
into the Egyptian and Ottoman [and also the Chinese] financial
ministries, the IMF is insinuated into the inner sanctums of nearly
75 developing country governments around the world-countries with
a combined population of some 1.4 billion."
In 1997, the IMF roared into a panic-stricken Asia, promising
to supply $17 billion to Bangkok, $40 billion to Jakarta, and
$57 billion to Seoul. In return, however, it demanded the imposition
of austerity budgets and high interest rates, as well as fire
sales of debt-ridden local businesses to foreign bargain hunters.
It claimed that these measures would restore economic health to
the "Asian tigers" and also turn them into "open"
Anglo-American-type capitalist economies. At an earlier meeting
at Manila in November 1997 called to deal with the crisis, Japan
and Taiwan had offered to put up $100 billion to help their fellow
Asians, but the U.S. Treasury's assistant secretary, Lawrence
Summers, denounced the idea as a threat to the monopoly of the
IMF over international financial crises, and it was killed. He
did not want Japan taking the lead, because Japan would not have
imposed the IMF's conditions on the Asian recipients and that
was as important to the U.S. government as restoring them to economic
health.
In Indonesia, when the government ended its dollar peg and
let t~ currency float, the rupiah fell from about 2,300 to 3,000
to the dollar but then stabilized. At that point, with almost
no empirical knowledge of Indonesia itself, the IMF ordered the
closure of several banks in a system that has no deposit insurance.
This elicited runs on deposits at all other banks. The wealthy
Chinese community began to move its money out of Indonesia to
Singapore and beyond, and the country was politically destabilized,
leading ultimately to the overthrow of President Suharto. All
Indonesian companies with dollar liabilities rushed to sell rupiahs
and buy dollars. Equities instantly lost 55 percent of their value
and the currency, 60 percent. The rupiah ended up trading at 15,000
to one U.S. dollar. David Hale, chief economist of the Zurich
Insurance Group, wrote at the time, "It is difficult, if
not impossible, to find examples of real exchange rate depreciations
comparable to the one which has overtaken the rupiah since mid-1997."
He suggested that a proper comparison might be with the hyperinflation
that hit the German mark in 1923.
By the time the IMF was finished with Indonesia, over a thousand
shopkeepers were dead (most of them Chinese), 20 percent of the
population was unemployed, and a hundred million people-half the
population-were living on less than one dollar a day. William
Pfaff characterized the IMF's actions as "an episode in a
reckless attempt to remake the world economy, with destructive
cultural and social consequences that could prove as momentous
as those of l9th-century colonialism " Only Japan, China,
and Taiwan escaped the IMF juggernaut in East Asia. Japan kept
aloof even when the Americans publicly rebuked it for failing
to absorb more exports from the stricken countries, for the Japanese
knew that the Americans would not actually do anything as long
as the marines were still comfortably housed in Okinawa. China
remained largely untouched because its currency is not freely
convertible and it had paid no attention to APEC calls for deregulation
of capital flows. And Taiwan survived because it had been slow
in removing its financial barriers. It also maintains a relatively
low ratio of investment to gross domestic product, is shifting
further toward a service economy whose capital needs are less,
and has maintained export diversity- unlike, for example, Korea's
overconcentration in products such as semiconductors destined
for the American market. Foreign holdings of Taiwanese currency
are negligible because its peculiar political status makes it
unattractive to the hedge funds. Thus, it has been able to offer
some of its own huge foreign currency holdings to help bail out
countries in Southeast Asia.
After the big investors had pulled their money out of East
Asia and left the area in deep recession, they turned to Russia.
They calculated that there was little or no risk in buying Russian
state bonds paying 12 percent interest because the Western world
would not let a former superpower armed with nuclear weapons default.
But the situation was further gone in Russia than these investors
imagined, and so, in August 1998, the Russians defaulted on the
interest payments (they still owe foreign investors perhaps $200
billion) If Russia does not repay these loans, it will be the
largest default in history. These developments so scared the finance
capitalists that they started pulling their money in from all
over the world, threatening even well-run economies that had implemented
all the economists' nostrums on how to get rich like the North
Americans. The Brazilian economy was so destabilized that in mid-November
1998 the IMF had to put together a $42 billion "precautionary
package" to shore it up. Needless to say, the IMF has also
helped plunge millions of poor Brazilians deeper into poverty.
In order to meet the IMF's austerity requirements, the Brazilian
government even had to cancel a $250 million pilot project to
save the Amazon rain forest. The result was that other countries
withdrew their matching funds for the Amazon, and the degradation
of an area that contributes 20 percent of the globe's fresh-water
supply resumed.
In speeches in Russia and East Asia during the second half
of 1998, President Clinton warned the peoples of these areas not
to "backslide" and urged them to open their nations
even further to American-style laissez-faire capitalism. But he
had lost his audience. By now his listeners understood that the
cause of their misery could not also be its cure. Many remembered
that the Great Depression started as a financial panic then made
worse by deflationary policies similar to those prescribed by
the IMF in 1997 and 1998 for East Asia, Russia, and Brazil. The
result in the early 1930s was a general collapse of purchasing
power. That has not happened so far this time, largely because
the United States went on a consumption binge and provided virtually
all growth in demand for the excess output of the world. Can American
"shop till we drop" be sustained indefinitely. No one
knows.
The economic crisis at the end of the century had its origins
in an American project to open up and make over the economies
of its satellites and dependencies in East Asia. Its purpose was
both to diminish them as competitors and to assert the primacy
of the United States as the globe's hegemonic power. Superficially
it can be said to have succeeded. The globalization campaign significantly
reduced the economic power and capitalist independence of at least
some of the United States" 'tiger" competitors-even
if, as with Russia and Brazil, the crisis could not be kept within
the bounds of East Asia. This was, from a rather narrow point
of view, a major American imperial success.
Despite such immediate results, however, the campaign against
Asian-style capitalism (and the possibility that America's satellite
states in the area might gain independent political clout as well)
was ill-founded and included serious blowback consequences. The
United States failed to acknowledge that East Asian success had
depended to a considerable extent on preferential, Cold War-based
exports to the American market. By cloaking its campaign in the
rhetoric of market opening and deregulation instead of the need
to reform outdated Cold War arrangements, the United States both
destroyed the credibility of its economic ideology and betrayed
its Cold War supporters. The impoverishment and humiliation of
huge populations from Indonesia to South Korea was itself blowback
enough, even if the blowback for the time being spared ordinary
Americans. But if and when the stricken economies recover, they
will almost certainly start to seek leadership elsewhere than
from the United States. At a bare minimum, they will try to protect
themselves from ever again being smothered by the American embrace.
In short, by refusing to reform its Cold War structures and instead
insisting that other peoples emulate the American way, the United
States gave itself an unnecessary, possibly terminal case of imperial
overstretch. Instead of forestalling global instability, it helped
make such instability inevitable.
The triumphalist rhetoric of American leaders basking in their
economy's "stellar performance" has also alarmed foreigners.
When Alan Greenspan asserted to Congress that the crisis meant
the world was moving toward "the Western form of free market
capitalism," almost no one thought that was either true,
possible, or desirable. Economics has not displaced culture and
history, regardless of the self-evaluation of the economics profession.
Many leaders in East Asia know that globalization and the crisis
that followed actually produced only pain for their people, with
almost no discernible gains. Globalization seems to boil down
to the spread of poverty to every country except the United States.
Blowback
- The Costs and Consequences of American Empire
U.S.
Foreign Policy
Index
of Website
Home
Page