The Global Economy
and the Decline of Social Reform
excerpted from the book
Globalization
and the Decline of Social Reform
by Gary Teeple
Garamond Press / Humanity Books, 2000, paper
p51
The Global Economy and the Decline of Social Reform
Changes in the postwar development of the welfare state became
evident during the 1970s, and despite national variations these
changes revealed numerous international parallels. In the context
of fiscal crises and lower rates of growth, governments introduced
shifts in tax structures, caps on public spending, wage and price
controls, and "anti-inflation" monetary policies. Further
expansion of reforms slowed or stopped, and the principle of the
welfare state itself began to come under attack.
The general cause of these shifts was not a changed political
vision but rather what has come to be called the "new reality,"
the byword for the internationalization of capital, the coming
of the global economy. In this new world market capital became
"denationalized," that is, characterized by such a high
degree of productive capacity and interlocking trade and investment
that it cannot be said to have a national home. This is not to
say that the largest and most industrialized nations no longer
act in the interests of their "national" capital or
that the national state is no longer an important source and means
of capital accumulation. It is, however, to say that, once internationalized,
capital: 1) requires "freedom" from national controls
or intervention; 2) has ultimately no national allegiance; 3)
has interests that span the world and far exceed national jurisdictions;
and 4) operates within a world economy and possesses a "global
perspective" in which domestic or national markets form only
one element and indeed are too small for the productive capacity
it possesses. The global economy produces its own demands that
are distinct from those of the national economy. It also produces
an integrated international arena that is both distinct from and
a challenge to bounded and protected national economies, now moribund
as such but characteristic of the development of capitalism up
to the 1970s.
It follows that the persistence of a national framework in
the form of trade barriers, monetary and fiscal regulations and
institutions, and a vast number of laws and standards must be
overcome. Just as with the formation of the nation-state in the
eighteenth and nineteenth centuries, when local and regional barriers
to trade had to be eliminated and national standards established
in order to provide the possibilities for capital to expand more
or less unfettered within a defined geographic territory, so too
national standards and barriers to trade now have to be eliminated
to allow capital to compete without such restraints in a global
economy. We have arrived at the end of the era of the nation-state,
and its declining significance is an important factor in the erosion
of social reforms. Economic powers are now able to determine the
direction of development at the international level, where compromises
with national working classes, and indeed national governments,
are not so necessary.
The Coming of the Global Economy
Throughout the history of the capitalist mode of production
there has been an expanding world market. Capitalist classes have
always sought to encompass and capitalize not only their domestic
markets but also the "external" market. Such expansion,
moreover, has been facilitated by a corresponding growth in the
size and power of the state, in the public debt, and in financial
mechanisms, that is, in international banking and credit facilities.
There have also been correlative developments in the nature of
the labour supply: the development of capitalism engendered the
forcible "freeing" of farmers or peasants from their
land, the enslavement of non-Europeans, the purchase of indentured
or bonded workers, the export of convicts, and the use of child
labour.
To be sure, a world economic system was evolving, but it was
coming about through the expansion of nationally defined corporations
that were branching out, in competition with other capital formations,
to increase their overseas territorial dominions as markets for
their commodities, sources of raw materials, and avenues for investment.
It was defined by the increasing interdependence of national capitals,
but it was still a system of national capitals whose interests
were promoted by a national state, and whose expansion gave rise
to the modern colonial system, forms of protectionism, and international
wars.
By World War I, the most industrialized national capitals
supported by state military power had divided the world into spheres
of influence, but they had also spilled over their national foundations
in other ways.
They had formed international cartels, trusts, and banking
syndicates for the control of world markets; and after the First
World War they had attempted to create international organizations
and regulatory agreements to mitigate imperial rivalry (League
of Nations), to regulate inter-imperial trade, investment, and
capital markets (Bank of International Settlements, BIS), and
to help guard against the expansion of socialism (the tripartism
of the International Labour Organization, ILO).
Despite these transnational beginnings, the world economic
order between the two world wars remained dominated by competing
national capitals. The Second World War, like the First, represented
competition between national capitals raised to the level of the
mobilization of the resources of the entire nation. It was, however,
to be the last of such wars.
The immediate preconditions of globalization lay in World
War II, the last major conflict characterized by the expansion
of capital in its national form. Prior to that war, capital was
largely national in character, and corporate interests, as "national
interests," were jealousy guarded at home and abroad by means
of standing armed forces, tariff barriers, currency controls,
and nationalism and citizenship, among numerous other national
laws and policies. The war represented the historical denouement
of the contradiction between the continuous impetus of capitalist
expansion and its form as the nation-state.
From the point of view of capital, the war's end presented
two dilemmas: how to reconstruct capitalism in Europe - but in
a way that avoided rebuilding the contradiction between expanding
capital and its national political form - and how to contain socialism,
a form of property antithetical to the growth of capitalism. The
solutions were more often than not combined in the same developments.
For the capitalist nations, the period between World War II
and the 1970s constituted an interregnum between the age of competing
imperial powers and the coming of the global economy. As the pre-eminent
capitalist power at the end of the war, the United States was
in a position to restructure the postwar world to reflect its
own interests. Those interests, however, were in essence the interests
of capital as capital, albeit still in national guise. Given this,
the U.S. restructuring of the postwar capitalist world marked
the beginning of the resolution of the contradiction that had
given rise to both world wars. The world as it was - national
governments representing national corporations - could grow no
further except to encounter more collisions between national forms
and with the obvious outcomes - bilateralisms, commercial warfare,
national economic problems, and war. Moreover, given new atomic
weaponry, another world war between the industrial nations had
become unthinkable.
So began a period in which the boundaries of international
relations were largely prescribed by the claims and exigencies
of one imperial power. The "international regime" introduced
after the war was a reflection of the international demands of
U.S. corporate interests. As the dominant postwar power, hitherto
limited in its access to the European and Japanese economies and
their colonies or spheres of influence, the United States was
intent on opening up new markets to itself. Its efforts were to
lay the groundwork for a single world economy of competing capitals.
Establishing a global 'enabling framework'
The U.S.-designed postwar rapprochement saw the creation of
political and economic structures and policies that remained dominated
by the United States throughout the period. Under U.S. auspices
in 1944, the future members of the United Nations (UN) held a
conference at Bretton Woods and established the basis of an international
monetary system. The delegates created an exchange-rate mechanism
by setting the parities of national currencies against the U.S.
dollar; and they established, among others, two institutions,
the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and the World Bank (WB).
The IMF was intended to regulate international trade balances,
but its general function was described as "a sort of Magna
Carta for a future world economic order." The World Bank
was designed to manage an international fund for economic development.
Alongside these mechanisms, the General Agreement on Tariffs and
Trade (GATT, established in 1947) would provide the institutional
means for a negotiated removal of all national barriers to world
trade and to create universal regulations for increasingly freer
commerce.
Although these economic institutions and agencies were of
primary importance after the war, the United Nations, dominated
by the United States, was formed as the beginning of supranational
quasi-government, as the political foundation for the new internationalism.
Among other things, the UN took upon itself powers to oversee
the long process of decolonization (one of the purposes of peace-keeping
operations), which in most instances aided U.S. penetration into
the former European colonies and advanced the geographic expansion
of the capitalist mode of production and the destruction of remaining
precapitalist modes. The UN was also employed to contain the expansion
of socialism (Korea, the Congo, Greece, Indonesia), to promote
the principles of liberal democracy and the rights of private
property as a political system consistent with the advance of
capitalism, and to establish international laws grounded in private
rights for the "world community."
Although the United Nations appeared to be the embodiment
of a genuinely democratic and multilateral world in the making,
it was dominated by an executive (the Security Council), whose
members (with the exception of the U.S.S.R.) were largely beholden
to the United States. The UN was, moreover, financially dependent
on the United States, as were most of its member nations, making
it largely an instrument to make the world over in the image of
America. This quintessentially capitalist nation and the principles
that it stood for were to be the model for the new world in the
making, and U.S. dominance in supranational agencies and institutions
remains to this day.
The liberal democracy promoted and established in the former
Axis regimes and the decolonized world was the Trojan Horse of
the new order - it held no intrinsic national character. Its principles
were the principles of corporate private property, and the political
system would amount to the periodic choice of different policies
within this property regime; and as a result those principles
would ultimately overreach national barriers. The assertion of
national interests was possible, and they were promoted, to be
sure, but in the final analysis national goals would prove contrary
to the embedded political principles.
Besides liberalized world trade, the containment of socialism,
and the furtherance of liberal political and legal principles,
another pillar of the new internationalism was the aggregation
of national markets. As early as the late 1940s the United States
encouraged the European countries to see their future as the "United
States of Europe" (a larger market for the postwar expansion
of capital), and to this end they entered into the Organization
for European Economic Co-operation (OEEC), whose main function
was to promote intra-European free trade. The Treaty of Rome (1957)
soon followed, establishing the progressive growth of a European
economic community. But Europe was not alone; by the 1960s, almost
the entire world was part of one or another customs union, common
market, or free-trade area.
Although engineered by the United States to suit its economic
needs and prevent the imperial conflicts of the past, this rapprochement
contained contradictions that were to frame the period of its
existence. The most obvious concerned the ascendency of U.S. military
and economic power over the industrial nations of Europe and Japan.
In effect, the United States represented one configuration of
national capital interests, albeit the most powerful, in a postwar
world in which other national capitals and their states were far
from moribund, and in which their economic reconstruction was
necessary to the success of the new world order. A second contradiction
involved the persistence of national interests in the face of
the developing "international regime." With no realistic
alternative to an international future, national capitals were
confronted with the dilemma of defending national interests while
embracing the internationalism necessary for expansion. Another
contradiction came with the struggle between capitalism and socialism
as the two main postwar roads to the future.
Throughout Europe the spread of socialism after the war as
a promise of workers' power and a form of property antithetical
to capitalism was pervasive. To ensure the future of capitalism,
socialism had to be contained, and to this end the U.S. administration
took up several initiatives. One comprised a massive financing
of capitalist reconstruction on strictly U.S. terms (UNRRA- the
United Nations Relief and Rehabilitation Administration, set up
in 1943 to provide material relief for liberated nations - and
the European Recovery Programme, or Marshall Plan, initiated in
1947), which involved a substantial degree of state intervention
in both capital and working-class reproduction. Another involved
the U.S. promotion of Keynesianism as a means of reconstruction
that gave the working class varying degrees of protection from
the effects of capitalism and involvement in its reconstruction.
To affirm the U.S. commitment to this reconstruction of capitalism,
a military alliance, NATO, was created in 1949 with a permanent
U.S. commander-in-chief ensuring that country's military dominance
over Europe. In addition the postwar period saw interference in
European elections, political parties, government policies, and
trade union movements.
Although socialism as state capitalism was ultimately abandoned
in the 1980s and 1990s, the postwar period saw the consolidation
of Soviet hegemony over Eastern Europe, the victory of the Chinese
People's Liberation Army, and numerous wars of liberation in former
colonial countries. All of these events suggested that the socialist
road might indeed succeed, a possibility that was always implied
in the co-operative military and economic arrangements of the
interregnum.
The same problems of rebuilding and consolidating capitalism,
containing socialism, and ending national barriers to accumulation
also presented themselves in the European colonial empires and
spheres of influence. Within one decade of the end of World War
II, struggles of national liberation arose in most of the colonial
world: in Vietnam, China, Malaysia, Dutch East Indies, Korea,
the Philippines, and India; in Algeria, Egypt, and Kenya; and
in the Middle East. For U.S. capital, and capital in general,
the socialist and nationalist movements of liberation had to be
fought or co-opted, and the colonial systems had to be dismantled
and opened to international trade. While military means were employed
in many of these cases, greatly supported by the United States,
the chief means of disengaging the colonial link and establishing
the foundations of a capitalist economy were United Nations peacekeeping
(both military and diplomatic operations) and the installation
in the colonies of liberal-democratic or dictatorial regimes as
required. The colonial systems could no longer be tolerated because
their very nature favoured restricted trade relations with the
metropole, while liberal democracy (or, in many cases, authoritarian
systems) opened the door to foreign investment and embraced the
principles that would ultimately supersede the structure of the
nation-state.
To bring an end to colonialism and to ensure that the newly
independent countries remained within the orbit of international
capital accumulation, the preferred solution appeared to be a
form of political independence embracing the formalities of liberal
democracy and constitutionally entrenched principles of private
property. Neo-colonialism - the subordination of former colonial
countries mainly by economic means and principles - was established
as the new relation between the industrial metropoles and the
"lesser developed" nations. Transformed from colony
to nominally independent nation-state, from subordination to one
industrial metropole to compliance with the new international
regime of corporate private property, most of the former colonies
were, under the guise of political freedom, opened to international
trade. A political shell of independence without the "content"
of an indigenous capital formation obscured the real content,
which was in essence the multinational corporation of the industrial
world.
From the point of view of capital, both the war and its aftermath
represented the restoration of the conditions for renewed accumulation.
The war brought an end to economic depression, with state intervention
in labour supply (regulated wages, restricted union activity,
and even slave-labour in Germany and Japan) and in corporate assistance
(superprofits and tax concessions for war production); government
mobilization of public and private capital; and the destruction
of inventories and new products in the war effort. After the war,
the basis for renewed accumulation became the reconstruction of
the devastated economies, again promoted by state-levered capital
for the corporate sector by means of deficit financing, increased
taxes, debased money, and, very importantly, U.S. "aid,"
particularly in the form of UNRRA and the Marshall Plan. Moreover,
new markets and sources of raw materials emerged as many of the
former colonial territories were opened to international capital.
Within a decade after 1945, the main elements of a framework
of a supranational regime of accumulation, albeit dominated by
the United States, had been established. There were the principles
of liberal democracy ensconced in the United Nations, Marshall
Aid for reconstruction, the IMF, World Bank, and GATT to regulate
and liberalize world trade, incipient common markets promoted
everywhere, and U.S. military control and influence throughout
the world. All these facets of the postwar world order were progressively
realized and operative by the end of the 1960s. A foundation had
been laid for the regulation of multinational corporations that
in principle transcended bilateral or multilateral relations between
nation-states. This global regulatory regime was an essential
precondition, a necessary and complementary part of the | e of
the transnational corporation and the process of globalization.
p61
The decline of national sovereignty
... extranational economic expansion was eroding the power
and influence of the national state. Corporate trade and investment
overseas were growing dramatically as a percentage of total operations,
and the multinational corporations (MNCs) had begun shifting profits
and operations to places where the advantages in taxation, wages,
or state support were greatest. Increasingly, they assumed the
powers of sovereign entities, ignoring and interfering in the
interests of nation-states. This expansion of the MNCs added international
pressure to remove national barriers and level the costs of corporate
activities. The rise of foreign currency and international capital
markets, moreover, meant not only that these economic functions
were increasingly outside the control of national regulation,
but also that they increasingly set the limits, as independent
markets, on national policies with respect to credit systems,
money supply, exchange and interest rates, debt-management, investment
policies, and taxation.
The growing erosion of the role and powers of the national
state was also visible in the rise of supranational accords or
treaties, multilateral agreements and organizations that all in
their own way began to restrict national sovereignty. Between
1945 and the early 1970s, international government organizations
(IGOs) and international non-governmental organizations (INGOs)
broadened their powers and increased by about threefold in number,
such that by the end of the 1970s there was hardly an aspect of
national life in industrial countries that was not addressed in
some way by a supranational body. Military multilateralism in
the shape of NATO, the Warsaw Pact, the United Nations, and other
regional pacts took the place of the independent national exercise
of armed force outside national borders. National policies on
international trade, scientific and technical standards for goods
and services, transportation and communication, employment and
health standards, and pollution were all increasingly subject
to modification and reformulation to bring them into accord with
internationally set rules and regulations.
The decline in powers of the national state was also reflected
in the worldwide increase in preferential trading groups. Although
the most important and earliest was the European Economic Community
(EEC) in 1958, there was not a single region in the world, including
the centrally planned economies, that had not attempted to create
a common market, customs union or free-trade area between the
1950s and the mid-1970s. Despite certain political resistance
and at times faltering success, economic interdependence at the
global and regional levels had everywhere profoundly circumscribed
national sovereignty.
The two-tiered development of the interregnum
From 1945 to the early 1970s, capitalism developed in a two-tiered
manner that reflected the nature of the postwar rapprochement:
the state-managed reconstruction of capitalism took place within
the nation-state, while at the same time the framework for international
free trade was undermining the national economy, the rationale
of the nation-state. The contradiction between the national form
of capital and the intrinsic drive of capital to overcome this
shell was moving towards its resolution with the erosion of this
rationale. Given the expanding supranational economic framework,
the size and power of MNCs, and the actual global development
of capitalism, the only resolution remaining to the contradiction
was the dismantling of the national shell. By the early 1970s,
the national relations of production were increasingly seen by
transnational corporations (TNCs) as mere fetters to intercorporate
relations at the global level.
Throughout this postwar period, and corresponding to the growth
of MNCs and international government organizations, there arose
international strata of bureaucrats, technocrats, academics, and
corporate managers, owners, and advisors. They managed the agencies
and organs of supranational governance, and the highest placed
also met regularly in certain forums for the express purpose of
discussing global trends and policies for the advance of certain
interests. Besides the more "public" venues, such as
UN agencies, the Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development
(OECD), and GATT, private venues such as the Trilateral Commission,
the Bilderberg conferences, the Club of Rome, and the so-called
think-tanks such as the Mont Pelerin Society and the Heritage
Foundation were all employed for these purposes. While not coherent
as a national government, here nevertheless was a growing matrix
of "public" and private organizations for decisionmaking
and policy-formation at the global level that became increasingly
influential as the demands for a global economy increased, and
that formed the meeting-ground for transnational strata occupied
with the advancement of a global economy.
It is perhaps not possible to say when the global economy
became a reality as distinct from interrelated national economies,
but certainly by the mid-1970s the end of the interregnum could
be seen in two significant developments. One was the extensive
reduction in barriers to world trade and production: the productivity
of the advanced Fordist mode of production possessed the capacity
for world supply, and the postwar "enabling framework"
had gone far to erode national restrictions. The other was the
loss of U.S. national paramountcy, signaled by several events.
Perhaps the most important was the suspension of the convertibility
of the dollar into gold in 1971, which ended the fixed exchange
rate mechanism that had so benefited U.S. expansion. Another was
the waning of the rate of U.S. direct investment and exports to
Europe by the early 1970s, while European and Japanese products
and capital began to claim ever greater shares of the U.S. market.
Also about this time the United States had begun to lose some
of its edge in technological superiority to Germany and Japan.
On the surface, the United States appeared to be yielding to these
rival economic powers; in effect, it was succumbing to the internationalization
of capital - built on a foundation that Washington itself had
forced on the world. Americanization was becoming tempered by
internationalization; the premise was becoming absorbed by its
conclusion.
There were other harbingers of the end of the interregnum
or the approaching global economy, and all were consequences of
two decades of unprecedented capital accumulation. One was the
near completion of decolonization and the consequent "opening
up" of the entire globe (with the exception of the "socialist"
countries) to capitalization. The world was now in effect subjected
to the capitalist mode of production. Another precursor was the
transformation of increasing numbers of multinational corporations
into TNCs, defined by the expanding internationalization of their
production and decline of a meaningful home base or domestic market.
Related to this development was the rising importance of international
foreign exchange and capital markets and of supranational agreements
and organizations, and the consequent increasingly obvious erosion
of national identity and sovereignty, not to mention the globalization
of culture.
Ironically, at the culmination of this interregnum, and before
the transformation of the nation-state was about to begin in earnest,
the voice of the non-corporate sector began to be heard. In the
industrialized nations, a citizenry that had come to believe that
their right to vote gave them power over policy began to demand
and expect a progressive extension of the welfare state - demands
characterized by the corporate sector as the "ungovernability
of democracy." In the decolonized nations, leaders labouring
under the belief that independence would bring freedom, democracy,
and material betterment and not a new form of colonization made
demands for an end to unequal exchange, a new international economic
order. More successfully, a group of oil-producing nations formed
a loose coalition (OPEC) and began to exact a somewhat fairer
share of oil revenues, albeit mainly for their own elites, from
the oil cartel. By the end of the 1970s, as the "new reality"
began to set in, these voices were silenced or compromised, or
had found other forms of expression.
By about 1970, the key institutional preconditions for a global
economy were in place; they had become a force of production in
the encouragement of global economic interdependence and helped
foster new means of production. Nevertheless, production was still
largely national, although much trade and commerce had turned
international. The movement to a global economy in which the circuit
of capital itself was global and national integrity weak and in
decline had not yet become manifest. About this time a dramatic
change in the technology of production, distribution, and circulation
began to be realized. These were changes that could not possibly
be contained within the framework of the nation-state.
p71
The Global Era
The trends towards the internationalization of capital during
the interregnum continued and intensified in the 1970s and thereafter.
Commodity trade expanded, though it was now in the shape of world
commodities in a world market: by 1980 the sales of many TNCs
in "foreign markets" increased to more than one-half
of total sales; and the imports and exports of all the industrial
nations, except Japan, increased as a percentage of the GNP. A
system of highly integrated world trade was an irreversible fact
by the end of the 1970s, confirmed and hastened by the new means
of transportation and communications, whose increased productivity
were transforming the worldwide distribution of products and hence
the global conditions for valorization. Also, with the coming
of computer-based systems, capitalist production became less constrained
by large-scale, long-term investments; and with the continuing
diminution of national barriers it could increasingly be "sited"
in regions or countries with the most favourable conditions for
accumulation (for instance, proximity to markets, types of labour
force, and state concessions). This locational flexibility of
productive capital became an important factor in the development
of a changing international division of labour, and the 1970s
saw a geographic restructuring of production leading to a rapid
rise in the world share of manufactured exports from developing
countries. Along with this came a growth in the Eurocurrency markets,
to such a degree that by the end of the 1970s the world's financial
markets were close to becoming a single integrated market.
Global labour market
All these changes worked towards the establishment of a global
labour market. The decolonization and capitalist penetration of
the non-industrialized countries after World War II gradually
created an enormous potential, internationally available labour
supply, previously "locked up" in precapitalist modes
of production or restricted to the needs of the capital of the
colonial "mother country." During the interregnum, an
unprecedented international migration from former colonies to
the metropolitan countries and enormous internal immigration in
the industrial countries from transformed sectors of the labour
market had provided a continuous supply of new labour power. Yet
given the sustained national growth rates and limited entry, the
supply was more or less readily absorbed until the early 1970s.
By this time, Europe and the United States had many millions of
ex-colonials and/or illegal immigrants forming a large "underclass"
of poor and unorganized workers, condemned to menial work, ineligible
for citizenship, restricted in legal rights, and limited in access
to the welfare state. The national working classes were to a large
degree insulated from the effects of these reservoirs of labour
as long as their position in an advanced Fordist mode of production
and growing public and unproductive sectors was maintained, and
as long as national laws controlled immigration and prevented
the integration of the underclass. Even so, these labour pools
produced a drag on minimum wages and therefore on the whole wage
structure; and despite their limited access to social security,
they reduced the redistribution of social surplus to the national
working class.
Just as national capital in the eighteenth and nineteenth
centuries had created national labour markets, so too had the
processes of trade liberalization, changes in the means of production,
and increasing international production begun to create an international
labour market by the mid-1970s. At this stage it was made up of
three main components: the "underclass" of displaced
and immigrant labour in the metropolitan countries, the labour
force in centres of cheap labour (Puerto Rico, Hong Kong, Singapore,
Dominican Republic), and workers in "free-enterprise zones"
or elsewhere, wherever commodities for the world market were produced.
The more that products from all the less-industrialized countries
entered the global market, the more that the value of the labour
power in these countries, and embedded in these products, became
a part of the internationalization of labour value.
The effects of this emerging global labour market began to
become visible from the early 1970s on with a general downward
pressure on wages in the industrial world. The incipient international
levelling of the value of labour power encouraged the rise of
female participation in the labour force, a growth in forms of
coerced or unfree labour, and the gradual reintroduction of child
labour.' Union bargaining rights began to confront increasing
legal restrictions, and union membership in the industrial nations
started to fall as the establishment of a growing surplus of low-wage
workers in the international labour market began to reduce both
the high demand for labour and upward pressure on wages. As permanent
unemployment climbed in the second half of the 1970s, high wages
declined, as did the social wage, and so began the deterioration
of the fiscal foundation of the KWS. The contemporary movement
towards world wages also commenced.
The making of a global capitalist labour market that will
encompass all the world's labour-power is far from complete. It
continues, as in the past, by the same legal, illegal, and coercive
means. The brutalities continue no less now than in the past,
with land clearances, forced emigration and transmigration, war,
slaughter, disease, and habitat destruction. The more or less
forceful proletarianization of that substantial part of humanity
that has not yet entered the capitalist labour market proceeds
apace. It is the creation of a labour market that is without protection
from either the national state or global agency. The supranational
framework that has developed exists by and large for capital alone;
no such labour-capital compromise as developed in the form of
the KWS in the industrial nations after World War II has appeared
at the global level.
p73
Capital has been outgrowing the very geographic and political
forms it had made for itself. By the end of the interregnum it
was superseding its own political framework, and the functions
of the state and meaning of nationality were being eroded and
becoming redefined at the supranational level. After the 1970s,
all the earlier trends towards internationalization continued,
beset by all the problems attendant on such a profound transformation.
TNCs increasingly assumed the powers of sovereign entities; the
markets in capital, commodities, and foreign exchange consolidated
their transnational existence; customs unions, common markets,
and free-trade areas embraced most of the countries of Europe
and the less developed world. Multilateral treaties and agreements,
military pacts, and the formation of numerous IGOs and INGOs covered
almost every aspect of economic activity, as well as significant
aspects of social and political life, placing constraints on national
independence. The authority of international laws increasingly
asserted itself over all national states. Even general policies
and programs for the globalization of the economy became subject
to transnational formulation in several venues, namely, in right-wing
think-tanks such as the Mont Pelerin Society and the Heritage
Foundation, in the Trilateral Commission, and in the annual economic
summits of the world's most advanced industrialized nations, known
as the Group of Seven (G7).
Without fear of exaggeration, it can be said that the national
state has lost and continues to lose much of its sovereignty,
although the degrees of independence vary with the degree of remaining
integrity to national economic and military formations. It is
not so much that a political state cannot act independently because
of the erosion or usurpation of its powers, but that its raison
d'etre- the existence of a nationally defined capitalist class
- has been waning. Taking its place has been the rise of an international
capitalist class with global interests. The idea of national considerations
is increasingly becoming an anachronism, as capital has by and
large lost its national character and seeks worldwide for advantages
for itself in the conditions of accumulation. The present role
of national states becomes the task of developing the international
mechanisms and agencies to facilitate and regulate the accumulation
of capital on a global scale. The more these are developed, the
more the functions of the national state themselves will be subverted.
p77
A second major effect of the "new reality" that
began to become evidently the late 1970s was the decline of social
reform everywhere in the industrialized nations. This retrenchment
began with the erosion of the conditions calling and allowing
for social reform.
Those conditions, multifold and interrelated, had begun to
change even before the 1970s. National capitals, as such, with
distinct national interests had begun to decline. The new agencies
and definers of policy and action were gradually becoming the
terms of membership in trading blocs, the world market, international
monetary agreements and institutions, and supranational political
and military organizations. The purpose and function of the national
state were becoming increasingly usurped by this "higher"
level, and its role began to shift more and more to merely "regional"
administration and security, and the facilitation of local capital
accumulation.
The ability of the state in the West to finance reform programs
went into decline, largely because of the falling rates of national
economic growth. But whether the rate was rising or falling, economic
growth no longer maintained the "positive" relation
it once had to "national" wealth in the form of corporate
tax revenues and high wages. Since the 1970s, corporations have
been more able than ever to play off nation against nation and
have taxes reduced while maintaining or increasing concessions.
Wage controls and inflation, moreover, have led to a decline in
real wages in many countries, while new technology has increased
the levels of long-term structural unemployment. An increased
tax burden on the working class has been the main factor offsetting
declining revenues. The future possibility of syphoning increasing
surpluses out of the Third World for the benefit of the industrial
countries would appear to be at an end. And the developing global
labour market has undermined the delimited national labour market
and thereby weakened the main condition allowing for the social
wage.
In addition to this declining ability to finance the welfare
state, increasing social needs, a depressed or shifting corporate
sector, decaying infrastructure, and approaching limits to taxation
on falling real incomes have placed increasing demands on state
expenditures. Together these pending limits, rising needs, corporate
blackmail, and falling potential for national economic expansion
have produced the chronic and growing state indebtedness that
further limits the resources needed to fund the KWS.
The existence of trade unions has been fundamental to the
achievement of social reform because they have been the main organized
force arising from the working class, and its only authentic voice.
With the introduction of computer-aided production in every sphere
of the economy, however, the nature of work and the structure
of the working class have changed. New strata have begun to arise,
but fewer overall; and structural, long-term unemployment grows
while most job creation is at the lower income levels. The global
labour market has begun to undermine wages and conditions of work
in the industrial nations. As a consequence of these developments,
the trade union movement has steadily been losing its members
and political and economic importance and has become more quiescent
and defensive. The national jurisdictions in which it grew and
was defined have become less and less relevant to business decisions.
In short, unions are left as national organizations in an era
of international forces. They begin to appear as anachronisms
because they have not for various reasons followed capital into
the international arena.
The conditions that gave rise to the welfare state are being
eroded or transformed. The nation-state is losing its raison d'etre,
that is, capital with a national identity; there is a decline
in "returns" from the Third World; a continuous revolutionary
restructuring of industry is creating weakened trade union movements,
a levelling of social strata, and a growth in long-term unemployment;
and the consequent changes in the tax-base and growing social
needs are increasing state indebtedness. Since the 1970s, when
the People's Republic of China shifted to the "capitalist
road," and since the early 1990s, when the U.S.S.R. collapsed
from its own bureaucratic weight, the threat of socialism in the
world, let alone in the West, has been minimized. If part of the
rationale of the KWS was to counter working-class attraction to
socialism, this concern has dissipated.
If the conditions of the postwar era - capital in its national
clothes with a nationally delimited labour market - led to the
creation of the KWS as the national mechanism for the reproduction
of labour and capital, it cannot be said that these conditions
obtain any longer. In the global market, capital can reproduce
itself with abundant cheap and unorganized labour from around
the world and with few and often no associated "external"
costs.
Another factor in this present transformation can no longer
be ignored. If the decline of social reform is increasingly leaving
social needs unanswered, there has never been much by way of environmental
reform, national or international, to confront the consequences
of planetary pollution caused by decades of industrial production
and consumption. "Nature" now appears as plundered and
polluted and in many places apparently unable to regenerate itself
in the short term. Several areas of the world's oceans have been
badly contaminated or fished out, huge expanses of forest have
been depleted, soil exhaustion and erosion are appearing everywhere,
fresh water sources are increasingly used up or poisoned, and
air in urban and industrial areas is polluted. The impact of this
destruction, which economists once considered as mere "externalities,"
is having a limiting effect on production itself. While critics
agree that these effects can no longer be ignored, governments
seek to minimize their import, mouthing concern but doing little
to clean up or prevent further destruction; and corporations resist
the idea of accepting responsibility for the external costs of
their industrial processes.
The decline of the conditions allowing for social reform means
that no matter which party assumes power, the possibility of continuing
those reforms associated with the KWS has been diminished. Such
policies were the product of the politics of the age of maturing
national capital, that is, capital in the imperialist era, which
implied international relations between nation-states, but not
global relations between organized capitals.
In this period of transition to a world economy, all political
parties in the industrial nations, including those whose tendency
is social-democratic, are confronted with the tasks of managing
a capitalist economy, now no longer national, with only the tools
of the moribund national state. Given this predicament, most parties
in the West coming into power since the mid-1970s have pursued
more or less similar policies - policies reflecting the demands
of internationalized capital, yet at the same time spelling out
the conditional end of the nation-state and its associated political
alternatives and social reforms.
Globalization
and the Decline of Social Reform
Index
of Website
Home
Page