Wealth and Politics in the
United States
Wealth, Money-Culture, Ethics,
and Corruption
Greed, Speculative Bubbles,
and Reform
excerpted from the book
Wealth and Democracy
a political history of the
American rich
by Kevin Phillips
Broadway Books, 2002, paper
p293
Theodore Roosevelt
There are only two kinds of rich-the criminal
rich and the foolish rich.
p293
Wealth and politics have a long history of intense interaction
in the United States. From the 1780s on, foreign visitors remarked
about Americans being money-fixated. John Stuart Mill, the English
political economist, suggested in 1860 that in America, "the
life of the whole of one sex is devoted to dollar-hunting, and
the other to breeding dollar hunters." A generation earlier,
Alexis de Tocqueville had observed that, "Whenever the reverence
which belonged to what is old has vanished, birth, condition,
and profession no longer distinguish men, or scarcely distinguish
them, hardly anything but money remains.... Among aristocratic
nations, money reaches only to a few points on the vast circle
of man's desires; in democracies, it seems to lead all."
p297
The Twelve Shared Characteristics of the "Capitalist Heyday"
Periods-the Gilded Age, the Roaring Twenties, and the Great Bull
Market of the 1980s and 1990s
1. Conservative politics and ideology,
with mostly Republican presidents but even Democratic presidents
in these eras - Grover Cleveland, Bill Clinton-tend to be economically
conservative.
2. Skepticism of government-from laissez-faire
to program cuts and deregulation-and emphasis on markets and the
private sector.
3. Exaltation of business, entrepreneurialism,
and the achievements of free enterprise.
4. Replacement of public interest politics
by private interest politics, with high levels of corruption.
5. Aspects of survival-of-the-fittest
thinking-from social Darwinism to welfare reform and globalization.
6. Labor union weakness and/or membership
decline.
7. Major economic and corporate restructuring-repeating
merger waves and the rise of trusts, holding companies, leveraged
buy-outs, spin-offs et al.
8. Obstruction, reduction or elimination
of taxes, especially on corporations, personal incomes, or inheritance.
9. Pursuit of disinflation-supportive
of creditors-in response to prior inflation (from the Civil War,
World War I, and the Vietnam era).
10. A two-tier economy with stronger prosperity
along the coasts and in the Great Lakes area, and greatest weakness
in the commodity-producing interior.
11. Concentration of wealth, economic
polarization, and rising levels of inequality.
12. Bull markets and rising, increasingly
precarious levels of speculation, leverage, and debt.
p308
with Socialist Eugene Debs, running on a government ownership
platform, carving out another 6 percent. This left William Howard
Taft, the incumbent conservative Republican, in third place with
just 23 percent. Business and finance had cause to be nervous.
Chapter 1 has told much of the story of
the rise of the "money issue" in the 1870s, 1880s, and
1890s. The objects of agrarian scorn were eastern finance, Wall
Street, and the "money power," more or less in that
order. New York and Philadelphia bankers had been targets since
the 1790s; Thomas Jefferson labeled financially-attuned Manhattan
"Hamiltonople" while Andrew Jackson loathed Chestnut
Street, the Philadelphia financial district where Nicholas Biddle
and the Second Bank of the United States had their white marble
lair. The insurgents of the 1870s, 1880s, and 1890s hurled their
epithets against "eastern finance"-"the East has
placed its hands on the throat of the West," said Sen. William
Allen of Nebraska-until "Wall Street" took over as the
preferred opprobrium.
In 1890 the Populist firebrand Mary Ellen
Lease, she who had urged Kansans to "raise less corn and
more hell," told her audiences that "Wall Street owns
the country. It is no longer a government of the people, by the
people and for the people, but a government of Wall Street, by
Wall Street and for Wall Street." Two years later Populist
presidential nominee James B. Weaver deplored how "Wall Street
has become the Western extension of Threadneedle and Lombard streets,"
the London location of the Bank of England. Eastern finance had
grown into what would become an enduring symbol.
For the farm states in particular, trying
to separate the various strands of late-nineteenth and early-twentieth-century
discontent may be pointless for reasons well-summarized by Professor
Russel Nye in his classic Midwestern Progressive Politics:
The whole inter-related problem of credit,
monopoly, currency and tariff fused into one major issue in the
Midwest-the impoverished farmer versus the Eastern "money
king." The railroad man, the monopolist, the speculator,
the banker, the mortgage holder, the manufacturer, all merged
into a single composite creature, the "plutocrat," whom
the farmer hated and feared. The "plutocrat" planted
no corn or wheat, built no towns, and battened on the labor of
those who did; he foreclosed mortgages, raised freight rates,
charged high interest, stole public lands and bought legislatures.
The "money power" was an old
term used by Jacksonians and then Populists. The more conspiracy-minded
among them saw the moneymen as the root of all evil: the dragon
whose slaying would remove most other problems. Kansas senator
William Peffer, for example, promised that, "With the destruction
of the money power, the death knell of gambling in grain and other
commodities will be sounded."
Hitherto vague, the term took on new (and
more specific) meaning during the Progressive era as shorthand
for the interlocking groups of banks, investment firms, and insurance
companies through which J. P. Morgan was said to control American
finance. A congressional (Pujo Committee) investigation in 1912
laid out the supposed interlock. The Morgan interests at the helm
of the system held 341 directorships in 112 corporations (insurance,
trading, manufacturing, transportation, and utilities) with a
capitalization totaling $22 billion. This single network of interests,
foes charged, commanded more than twice the assessed value of
all real and personal property in the thirteen southern states
and indeed more than the assessed value in all twenty-two states
west of the Mississippi.
Curbing the money power was one of Woodrow
Wilson's ambitions, albeit naive, in pushing the Federal Reserve
Act of 1913. In his "New Freedom" speech of 1912, Wilson
worried: "We have been dreading all along the time when the
combined power of high finance would be greater than the power
of the government. Have we come to a time when the President of
the United States or any man who wishes to be President must doff
his cap in the presence of this high finance, and say 'You are
our inevitable master, but we will see how we can make the best
of it'?" However, the Federal Reserve did not turn out to
be the counterbalance Wilson had sought.
Franklin D. Roosevelt, after the success
of his 1933 speech excoriating "the unscrupulous money-changers"
who "stand indicted in the courts of public opinion, rejected
by the minds and hearts of men," took up related themes through
the 1936 elections. New Deal Democrats had passed the Glass-Steagall
Act to separate the ownership of banks and investment firms in
order to decouple bank profits and lending patterns from the stock
market. The Securities Exchange Act, in turn, prohibited stock
market pools, insider trading, and market manipulations while
creating a new Securities and Exchange Commission to police the
markets. The Federal Reserve Act was amended to give the board
power to curb margin loans and confine the purchase of U.S. government
securities by the regional Federal Reserve banks to what was needed
for their performance of open-market operations.
Roosevelt's sense that he was confronting
another incarnation of the
p317
Elizabeth Drew, The Corruption of American Politics, 1999
The most successful politicians are no
longer the best executives or the best legislators, but rather
the best fundraisers.
p317
R D. Tawney, British historian
A society which reverences the attainment
of riches as the supreme felicity will naturally be disposed to
regard the poor as damned in the next world, if only to justify
making their life a hell in this.
p317
Corruption, like larceny, comes in many forms, some blatant, others
more subtle. Booms, speculative heydays, and other periods of
money worship bring the highest ratios of both corruptions, the
hard and the soft. It stands to reason that bribery, embezzlement,
fraud, swindling, and other "hard"-criminal-forms of
avarice rise with the heat of soaring stock indexes, market worship,
and the glorification of consumption and gain. The 1980s and 1990s
saw political and governmental corruption in the United States
recapture the laxity of the Gilded Age and Roaring Twenties. In
the late twentieth century, however, venality was also endemic
among the other Group of Seven industrial nations-Japan, Germany,
Italy, France, Canada, and Britain-a moral convergence to match
the contagion of market-driven philosophy.
... Charles Kindleberger capsuled the
practical and philosophic interrelationships of financial booms
and unlawful behavior. A megaboom was bound to breed even more.
Many, many books and articles have explored the transgressions,
and the Wall Street Journal, in an ethical retrospective on the
nineties, acknowledged that "historians are intrigued by
the parallels they see between this era's frauds and those from
past periods of financial frenzy." From Kindleberger's research,
crashes and panics have often "been precipitated by the revelation
of some misfeasance, malfeasance or malversation {the corruption
of officials} engendered during the mania. It seems clear from
the historical record that swindles are a response to the greedy
appetite for wealth stimulated by the boom."
Less obtrusive but at least as important
has been the corollary corruption of thinking and writing-the
distortions of ideas and value systems to favor wealth and the
biases of "economic man." In this sense, too, the eighties
and nineties echoed the Gilded Age and the 1920s.
Unusual corruption amid periods of boom
and speculation goes back to ancient times. However, chroniclers
of the interplay between speculative finance and corruption in
Britain and the United States usually pick up their tale with
the "financial revolution" between 1690 and the 1720
implosion of the South Sea bubble. Rules and stock markets were
emerging together. Bribes of call options given to members of
Parliament to facilitate an East India Company charter in the
1690s led to the expulsion of the speaker of the House of Commons,
the impeachment of the lord president of the Council, and the
imprisonment of the governor of the East India Company. When the
famous South Sea Company stock bubble burst in 1720, crowds outside
Westminster howled for retribution against the stock-owning officeholders-some
one hundred lords and three hundred members of the House of Commons
had shares-who had cooperated in the laxity that had left the
populace "bubbled." Parliament expelled the four MPs
who were South Sea directors, and the chancellor of the exchequer
was sent to the Tower.
Transgressions were just as grand in the
Gilded Age. The Credit Mobilier scandal turned up proof that both
the previous and present vice presidents had been given railroad
stock to enlist their sympathies. During the Harlem Railroad battles
of 1864, members of the New York legislature openly speculated
against Vanderbilt's Harlem position, lost, and had to meet their
obligations. The old Commodore chortled that, "We busted
the whole Legislature, and scores of the honorable members had
to go home without paying their bills."
By 1892 the men and women writing the
preamble to the Populist platform were seething in recollection:
"We have witnessed for more than a quarter of a century the
struggles of the two great political parties for power and plunder
. . . to secure corruption funds from millionaires."
Of course, the bounds of honesty are always
being updated. In 1720 a man could hire a clerk but could not
count on his loyalty; the lines between business and theft were
imprecise. In the United States the borrowing of bank funds by
officials was not definitively ruled illegal until 1799. Insider
trading was outlawed in the U.S. in the 1930s, but not until 1980
by Britain and the late 1980s by Japan. In the meantime, new practices,
relationships, and gray areas have emerged.
By World War I the face of "corruption"
in the United States had been changed by reforms like popular
election of U.S. senators, direct primaries, initiatives and referenda,
and in some states even voter recall of judges. What muckraker
David Graham Phillips had called "The shame of the Senate"
was washed away. But criminal activity resurged in war contracts
and the loose climate of the twenties; witness the Teapot Dome
scandal, the corruption that came with Prohibition and bootleg
liquor, and the post-1929 convictions of dozens of financiers.
Still, the many New Deal securities and banking reforms enacted
between 1933 and 1935 point out just how many abuses had been
legal and common practice up to and even through the Crash.
One legacy of the New Deal was to infuse
American politics and policymaking with egalitarian and anticorporate
biases, which many business leaders and conservatives found offensive.
But beginning in the 1970s, as politics turned conservative again,
a group of conservative multimillionaires and foundations underwrote
an ever-growing network of policy journals, university chairs,
and think tanks. Originally funded in a small way to counter the
prevailing liberal bias, by the 1980s they had become influential
in constraining government and scripting new directions for tax
legislation, monetary policy, business regulation, and even judicial
decision-making.
The result by 2000 was a Washington in
which liberals found themselves muttering about "corruption"
that was largely legal behavior- decision-making lubricated by
so-called "soft money" political contributions, and
resulting in flagrant tax favoritisms, bank bailouts, gutted regulations,
and see-no-evil administration of the federal election laws. Little
of it was morally defended. In 1996, when the federal government,
after little debate, gifted some $70 billion worth of public spectrum-band
to the telecommunications industry, even several conservative
U.S. senators decried its resemblance to the freewheeling gifts
of public lands to the railroads a century earlier.
Indeed, through both "hard"
corruption-the straightforward, indictable kind-and the "soft"
variety, in which bribes wore veils and laws and regulations were
bent to dubious purposes, the domination of politics by wealth
and corporations circa 2000 bore some resemblance to the captivity
of the Senate by business a century earlier. Running for president
on the Green Party ticket, Ralph Nader, in the last few days of
the campaign, echoed the latter attacks of the Greenbackers and
Populists. "The two parties," he declared, "have
morphed together into one corporate party with two heads wearing
different make-up."
Richard N. Goodwin, former speechwriter
for John F. Kennedy, had several years earlier offered a Wilsonian
reprise: "The principal power in Washington is no longer
the government or the people it represents. It is the Money Power.
Under the deceptive cloak of campaign contributions, access and
influence, votes and amendments are bought and sold. Money establishes
priorities of action, holds down federal revenues, revises federal
legislation, shifts income from the middle class to the very rich.
Money restrains the enforcement of laws written to protect the
country from abuses of wealth-laws that mandate environmental
protection, antitrust laws, laws to protect the consumer against
fraud, laws that safeguard the securities markets, and many more."
But so long as the economy and stock market remained strong, much
of the electorate did not seem to care.
p321
Lord Acton's famous saying about power corrupting and absolute
power corrupting absolutely ...
p322
What made the Gilded Age was not the individual scandals of the
Reagan, Bush, or Clinton years... The new crux was the vast, relentless
takeover of U.S. politics and policymaking by large donors to
federal campaigns and propaganda organs. The S&L scandals
showed the corruption in both parties, and junk-bond king Michael
Milken claimed in a boast to the Washington Post that "the
force in this country for buying high-yield securities has overpowered
all federal regulation." Indeed, the eighties saw the financial
sector take the lead in Washington lobbying outlays and in dollars
provided to federal election campaigns. Both cemented a fast-returning
relationship: politics was finance, and finance was politics,
just as the men with diamond stickpins had said a century earlier.
Statistics help to tell the tale. From
relative peanuts in the early eighties, the money contributed
to federal politics by the finance, insurance and real estate
(FIRE) sector rose almost as fast as the money channeled to finance
by federal bail-outs and permissive regulation. According to the
Center for Responsive Politics, the totals contributed rose from
$109 million in the 1992 cycle to $162 million in the 1996 cycle
and a walloping $297 million in the 2000 cycle, by which point
the FIRE sector was collectively the largest giver. Of the total,
the sector was particularly prominent in contributions from individuals-$148
million that cycle-and in soft money ($108 million), the quietest
agent of influence. The congressional tax-writing committees were
a particular target, and during the 2000 cycle (which for senators
stretched from 1995-2000), the House and Senate committee members
received $45.7 million from individuals in all sectors, not just
FIRE.
The FIRE sector is also regularly the
biggest spender on lobbying of corruption of the 1980s and 1990s
rank with the all business sectors. It laid out more than $200
million-again based on Center calculations-in 1998, the year when
industry executives and lobbyists led by Citigroup co-CEO Sanford
Weill succeeded in convincing Congress to effectively revoke the
New Deal era Glass-Steagall Act which among other things separated
banks and insurance companies.
While a full portrait of the late-twentieth-century
money-culture excesses and their carryover may await 2015 or 2020,
one can see a basic resemblance to the four-decade period between
1870 and 1913. In its first stage, corruption took ten to fifteen
years to become clear. Then, over the next fifteen, money became
all-powerful while reform dawdled. The fourth decade, in each
case coinciding with the iconoclasm of a new century, saw popular
resentment of money politics and demand for remedies begin to
gain the upper hand.
We have seen how the late eighties and
nineties were the period of money's late twentieth-century rise
to dominate U.S. politics, paralleling the simultaneous ascent
of market philosophy and the boom in the financial markets. Besides
the likeness to the Gilded Age, there was also a resemblance to
the 1920s. Conservative theorists have ignored these overlaps,
rarely criticizing money in politics because of their predilection
for the example of markets-by definition places where things are
bought-and their hope to recast politics in a market mode. The
third-party candidacy of Ross Perot in 1992, which attacked corruption
and two-party domination in American politics, provided a brief
revitalization as money lost centrality and voter turnout jumped
to 55 percent from 50 percent in 1988. However, money was back
in 1994, fueling the Republican capture of Congress, and then
again in 1996 when both major parties' fundraising set records,
which were then shattered in the nineties. Chart 8.1 shows the
enormous sums coming into what some donors did indeed hope was
becoming a marketplace.
To convey some idea of the growth of campaign
finance since, say, the late seventies-and with it the pressure
on legislators to be able to enlist donors-Common Cause presented
the relevant statistics to a 1994 Congressional hearing. In 1976,
winning Senate incumbents laid out an average of $610,000 on their
races. By 1986, the figure had grown to $3 million. By 2000, the
average figure for all Senate incumbents was $4.4 million, while
the average winner in all races raised $7.3 million.
As the fundraising chase mounted, critics
of the political process focused more and more on the determinative
role of money in election outcomes. Reports by the Center for
Responsive Politics and Citizen Action contended that in the 1996
congressional races, the candidates who raised the most money
won 92 percent of the time in the House and 88 percent of the
time in the Senate. In the sixty House districts identified before
the election as toss-ups, Republicans had an average of 42 percent
more money to spend. By 1999, pundits began describing the initial
fundraising of presidential candidates a decisive "wealth
primary," pointing out
the close correlation between the frontrunners'
share of their party's early cash-60 percent for Republican George
Bush and 64 percent for Democrat Albert Gore-and their support
in the polls. Over the first six months of 1999 the $103 million
taken in by all presidential candidates was three times the amount
for the comparable period four years earlier.
Television helped create the nexus, being
a medium of marketing and entertainment-and an expensive one.
As television advertising took over elections, so did communications
markets and audience sampling. In 1999 and 2000, the Republican
and Democratic parties followed the market message to its logical
conclusion: raising ever-larger contributions in soft dollars-ostensibly
limited to use for party-building activities - from donors that
were overwhelmingly corporate.
The reaction by the Republican and Democratic
contenders taking the reform side was angry. Former New Jersey
senator Bill Bradley, the Democrat, insisted that "democracy
doesn't have to be a commodity that is bought and sold."
On the day front-runner George W. Bush announced having raised
$37 million, enough so that he could forgo federal matching funds
and avoid spending limitations, the reform-minded Republican,
Senator John McCain, denounced the campaign finance system as
"an elaborate influence-peddling scheme by which both parties
conspire to stay in office by selling the country to the highest
bidder."
McCain also denounced the House Republicans'
big tax bill glutted with provisions favorable to banking and
securities firms, oil and gas operators, and insurance and utility
companies, thought by some to be the quid pro quo for the many
millions in party donations. Charging that it broke the GOP promise
to deal with "corporate welfare," the Arizona senator
said, "Now we're going to see this big thick tax code on
our desks, ) and the fine print will reveal another cornucopia
for the special interests and a chamber of horrors for the taxpayers."
The Democrats, for their part, had pioneered
in 1996 on another dimension, raising funds abroad, of which many
came from international favor-seekers-apparently including intelligence
services of nations like China. President Clinton was embarrassed,
and some commentators believed that the preelection White House
fundraising scandal in 1996 helped influence voters to keep the
Republicans in control of Congress.
As with Mark Twain's writings during the
Gilded Age, satire could be devastating. During the 2000 campaign,
a group called billionairesforbushorgore.com, joining in the market
analogy, posted the following on their website:
While you may be familiar with stocks
and bonds, currency speculation, IPOs and all the rest, there's
a new investment arena you should be aware of: legislation. If
a mutual fund returns 20% a year, that's considered quite good,
but in the low-risk, high-return world of legislation, a 20% return
is positively lousy. There's no reason why your investment dollar
can't return 100,000% or more.
Too good to be true? Don't worry, it's
completely legal. With the help of a professional legislation
broker (called a Lobbyist), you place your investment (called
a Campaign Contribution) with a carefully selected list of legislation
manufacturers (called Members of Congress). These manufacturers
then go to work, crafting industry-specific subsidies, inserting
tax breaks into the code, extending patents or giving away public
property for free.
Just check out these results. The Timber
Industry spent $8 million in campaign contributions to preserve
the logging road subsidy, worth $458 million-the return on their
investment was 5,725%. Glaxo Wellcome invested $1.2 million in
campaign contributions to get a 19-month patent extension on Zantac
worth $1 billion-their net return: 83,333%. The Tobacco Industry
spent $30 million in contributions for a tax break worth $50 billion-the
return on their investment: 167,000%. For a paltry $5 million
in campaign contributions, the Broadcasting Industry was able
to secure free digital TV licenses, a give-away of public property
worth $70 billion-that's an incredible 1,400,000% return on their
investment.
p329
The second imprint left by the money culture
during eras of unleashed capital and speculation has been cultural
and intellectual: the marshaling of thinkers, writers, publications,
and academies on behalf of wealth, markets, and corporations.
Certain themes keep coming back like homing pigeons.
Human nature itself goes through stages
of self-interpretation. Conservative eras rediscover the greed
and marketplace, polish the image of freebooters like Jay Gould
and after awhile think nothing of drowning politics in money.
Liberals rediscover social justice, polish the image of Robin
Hood and after awhile, think nothing of drowning policymaking
in sociology. But for the millennial context, the open Pandora's
Box is "conservative." There is also a relevant literature
going back some six centuries that explains how yesteryear's private
sins and vices-individual compulsions to self-interest, avarice,
luxury, and pride-can and do reemerge from time to time as commercial
and civic virtue, indeed props of unusual national success.
p332
Especially in the 1890s, millionaires like Andrew Carnegie, John
D. Rockefeller, Chauncey Depew, and James J. Hill proudly identified
themselves as Darwinian selectees. Clawing self-interest had made
them the lions of the economic veldt, the commercial chosen ones.
Successful over three decades, social Darwinism probably represents
the longest-lasting philosophic shield ever held up by American
wealth accumulators.
By the end of the century, however, contrary
interpretations were catching hold. Thorstein Veblen in his famous
Theory of the Leisure Class (1899) mocked the idea that the avaricious
capitalists were any sort of "fittest." Indeed, the
self-interested "pecuniary" man, with his chicanery,
luxury, and conspicious consumption, far from turning these private
traits into a public virtue, played a predatory and morally delinquent
role. Oliver Wendell Holmes likewise turned the tables in a Massachusetts
state court opinion, trapping social Darwinism in its own Pleistocene
jungle by upholding a strike by organized labor as "a lawful
instrument in the universal struggle of life."
By the 1 920s the trinity of Darwinism,
conspicuous consumption, and economic self-interest were ready
for another boom-era revival. "The business of America is
business," proclaimed President Calvin Coolidge. Government
regulation was curbed and in some circumstances gutted. A few
years earlier even the pundit Walter Lippmann had linked democracy
to "the right to purchase consumer goods at low prices."
Bruce Barton, later a Republican congressman, published a book
portraying Jesus Christ as the world's first great salesman. Sinclair
Lewis, the iconoclastic novelist, wryly observed that "the
Romantic Hero was no longer the knight, the wandering poet, the
cowpuncher, the aviator, nor the brave young district attorney,
but the great sales manager, who had an Analysis of Merchandizing
Problems on his glass-topped desk, whose title of nobility was
'Go-getter....' "
Expansions of merchandising and consumption-the
ties to self-indulgence jump out-also tend to correlate with the
great economic upheavals, partly because the successful want to
put their achievement on display, but also because expansive "can't
help ourselves" popular consumption surges can be huge wealth
generators. The point is that great economic events and their
supporting philosophic justifications cross-fertilize each other.
The economic thrust may come first, but supporting ideology, with
its deification of self-interest, greed, and consumption, gives
boom and bull market circumstances greater momentum and longevity.
After the egalitarian milieus of the New
Deal, the Eisenhower years and even the early sixties, self-interest,
greed, and consumption made a major comeback during the Reagan
years. The new president said that, "More than anything else,
I want to see the United States remain a country where someone
can get rich," His treasury secretary, Donald Regan, J acknowledged
their hope of recapturing the 1920s, saying, "We're not going
back to high-button shoes and celluloid collars. But the President
does want to go back to many of the financial methods and economic
incentives that brought about the prosperity of the Coolidge period."
Adam Smith ties appeared all over Washington.
New magazines wooed economic ambition with titles like Inc., Venture,
Millionaire, Entrepreneur, and Success. Hostile takeovers, leveraged
buyouts, and junk bonds became the jousting lances. Risk arbitrageur
Ivan Boesky, one of their paladins, told cheering business school
audiences that, "Anyone who thinks greed is a bad thing,
I want to tell you that it's not a bad thing. And I think that
in our system, everybody should be a little bit greedy."
Fashion industry historians add their
insight that the Reagan years outconsumed the twenties. Through
a series of opulent New York parties centered on the Metropolitan
Museum of Art and several department stores, Nancy and Ronald
Reagan, advised by former Vogue and Harper's Bazaar editor Diana
Vreeland, appeared to be favoring a new "aristocracy."
Instead of producers, they saluted packagers and promoters: movie
stars, Hollywood glitterati, department store chief executives,
dress designers, media moguls, and fashion purveyors. Vreeland
herself had said, "Everything is power and money and how
to use them both.... We ? mustn't be afraid of snobbism and luxury."
p334
Milton Friedman had been an adviser to Barry Goldwater and then
Richard Nixon before "monetarism" got its name from
a sympathetic academician in 1968. Those on the Right liked the
downgrading of government in his theory that the money supply
itself was the key to both GNP growth and inflation management.
Governmental interference in the economy, Friedman advised, was
almost always counterproductive. He also excused both the stock
market crash and speculators from blame for the Great Depression;
that he assigned to the Federal Reserve.
Vice-into-civic-virtue theology had a
new set of rostrums. To Friedman, greed was the basis of society.
The challenge of social organization, he said, was to "set
up an arrangement under which greed will do the least harm: capitalism
is that kind of system." Speculators, seeking personal profit,
played a useful role. He dismissed the idea of a res pablica-a
public interest apart from individual and group self-interests.
One could almost see the ghosts of Mandeville, Spencer, and Sumner
snapping off salutes.
The larger "Chicago school,"
pushed to the forefront by the failures of sociology and liberal
"fine-tuning" economics in the 1960s and early 1970s,
emphasized a free-market core theology that broadly dismissed
the role of governments. A few enthusiasts proved embarrassing
with their claims that markets and economics also explained behavior
from racial discrimination to divorce, suicide, and drug addiction.
One such was Chicago law professor-turned-federal appeals court
judge Richard Posner's suggestion of a market for babies to make
it easier for couples to adopt. But the school's basic message
was unimpaired.
The pervasiveness of self-interest also
led economist Arthur Laffer and journalist Jude Wanniski in 1973-74
to place tax cut theology alongside market freedom in the pantheon
of the new politics. Republican economist Herbert Stein labeled
their work "supply-side fiscalism" because it called
for fiscal (tax) policy to strengthen the supply (investment)
side rather than the demand (Keynesian) side of the national economy.
This the two shortened to "supply side." They also acknowledged
borrowing from French economist Jean Baptiste Say (1767-1832),
whose dicta was that "supply creates its own demand."
Soon a third supply-side architect, George Gilder, took the idea
of supply creating its own demand back to the potlatch ceremonies
of the Kwakiutl Indians of the Pacific Northwest.
Potlatches or no, here was a rationale
for two important capitalist impulses-the desire to overinvest
and overproduce (without running afoul of slumping demand) and
to stimulate expansion through tax breaks for (rich) producers
rather than (relatively poor) consumers. The drawback, unfortunately,
involved the chastening memories of U.S. overproduction after
the Napoleonic Wars, again in the 1880s and 1890s, and then, most
conspicuously, in the 1920s. Overinvestment was also recurrent.
However, even if the real world had periodically discredited Say's
Law, supply-side enthusiasm helped enact the Reagan administration
tax cuts of 1981; businessmen were happy to applaud if not altogether
believe.
Wanniski's work was funded by a grant
from one of the small but influential group of conservative foundations.
Many more grants followed to others. By the late 1970s the funder
group included the John M. Olin, Sarah Scaife, Harry and Lynde
Bradley, and Smith Richardson foundations. Through the seventies
and eighties their decisions helped support and fortify American
enterprise along a broad front of intellectual engagement.
p337
Selfishness as civic virtue, however, also renewed its consumptionist
drumbeat. Researchers at the Dallas Federal Reserve Bank proffered
the thesis that household circumstances were best measured by
what the householders consumed, not the mere "proxy"
of earnings or income. Consumption, as glorified from the Renaissance
and the English regency to the fascination of president and Mrs.
Reagan with Oscar de la Renta, Bill Blass, Ralph Lauren, Yves
St. Laurent, and Bloomingdales has been an economic mainstay and
cultural fascination of heyday capitalism.
The economic utility of promoting consumption
is that during heydays the public typically pursues the most popular
new innovations and products-automobiles, radios, and movies in
the twenties, athletic shoes, video games, and cellular phones
toward the millennium-at the expense of such humdrum needs like
indoor plumbing, education, and medical care. Consumer spending
booms are also profits booms. Besides, using consumption as a
gauge works to overstate popular well-being, all the more so because
its measurements ignore assets and leave out debt burdens, which
climbed most during periods like the 1920s, 1960s, and the 1980s
and 1990s precisely for those least able to afford them.
By an even more expansive view, consumption
had become part of the new edifice of democracy-as-market. By
driving a car, buying a movie ticket, or watching a television
commercial, U.S. consumers participated every day in the democracy
of the marketplace, or so suggested the editorial pages of the
Wall Street Journal. What was widely purchased was, ipso facto,
democratically approved. Buying and selling, indeed, was a large
part of what democracy was about.
p339
Social Darwinism, in turn, made a further comeback through the
insistence by many political officeholders, financiers, and leaders
of multinational corporations that the onrush of globalization
was inevitable ... This time, the jungle in which the fittest,
both individual and corporate, would survive was to be worldwide.
"There is no alternative," said British prime minister
Margaret Thatcher. In the 1880s and 1890s social legislation had
been dismissed as the unwisdom of government meddling with evolutionary
inevitability. A century later a similar cloak of unstoppability
was thrown over the globalization of labor markets and management
of trade markets by corporate-dominated institutions like the
World Trade Organization.
A century earlier, reform legislation
had finally gathered momentum as social Darwinism was displaced
by early-twentieth-century Progressivism; pre-1914 globaiization
itself was badly wounded in the trenches along the Somme and Marne,
dying in the twenties and thirties with free trade and Liberal
England. Past "globalizations," as we have seen, were
not inevitable, but elite-driven and often related to the heyday
of a particular world power.
The 1990s brought a new wave of neo-Darwinian
self-assuredness. In 1999 billionaire Philip Hampson Knight of
Nike posed for Forbes' annual photograph alongside his corporate
reflecting pool, sneakered feet extended, with a snarl on his
lips against critics who charged him with making his shoes and
his profits through low-wage labor in Asian sweatshops. "That
isn't an issue that should even be on the political agenda today,"
said Knight. "It's just a sound bite of globalization."
But some of this confidence withered when the new century began
with mass rallies against the annual meeting of the World Trade
Organization.
In the mid-1980s, the historian Arthur
Schlesinger Jr. dismissed the Reagan-era package of conservative
economic issues-attacks on regulation, glorification of the unfettered
market, and embrace of supply-side (or "trickle-down")
tax policy-as being less new ideas than "the boilerplate
of every private interest era." Perhaps, but by 2000 the
conservative restatement of old-market theology, antiregulatory
shibboleths, God-wants-you-to-be-rich theology, and Darwinism
had built up the greatest momentum since the days of Herbert Spencer
and William Graham Sumner.
p340
Party watersheds have involved opposition to financial, mercantile,
or speculative elites, often (but not always) crystallized by
public reaction to an economic downturn that had begun under a
conservative regime. In the middle of conservative or Republican
cycles, however, amid boom circumstances, the Democrats tend to
lose their bearings and become almost as collaborative with heyday
capitalism as the dominant GOP. Examples include the Gilded Age
twin conservative administrations of Grover Cleveland, the pro-business
economics of congressional Democrats during the 1920s, the policies
of the Carter administration of 1977-81, and the money-culture
bias of the eight Clinton years with their bond market and Wall
Street orientation. The "corruption" here is that the
system loses an essential counterbalance.
p341
The Democratic presidencies during the post-1968 Republican era
continued to fit the pattern. Georgian Jimmy Carter, elected in
1976 in the wake of Watergate, was moderately conservative in
his economics, kept on close terms with home state bankers and
corporate chiefs (CocaCola and Lockheed), undertook financial
deregulation before Reagan, and appointed Paul Volcker, a moderate
with conservative leanings, as chairman of the Federal Reserve
Board. Liberal historian Schlesinger, after citing Carter's conservative
views-"Government cannot solve our problems. It can't set
our goals...." charged him with "an eccentric effort
to carry the Democratic Party back to Grover Cleveland."
In a number of ways Bill Clinton continued
where Carter left off. However, the nineties had also intensified
a larger transformation within the Democratic Party. Its internal
economic balance of power had shifted appreciably. This change
occurred between the 1950s, when the Democrats started showing
gains among college graduates and urban and suburban professionals,
and the 1 990s, when the onetime party of Jefferson and Jackson
emerged as the clear choice of many of the new Internet and telecommunications
rich headed to the top of the Forbes 400.
Much more was involved than the Democrats'
familiar practice of conforming to financial booms. The increased
party support visible among urban professionals after the late
1950s might have been no more than a new round of Mugwumps and
Progressives. What made the transformation deeper and different
was the rise of the knowledge sector ... the soaring numbers of
Americans employed in education, communications, research, and
professions from law to psychiatry. In the midst of the liberal
political failure of the late 1960s and early 1970s, Democratic
responsiveness to this sector was at first a political minus.
However, with the demographics looking far more auspicious, Will
Marshall, president of the "New Democrat" Progressive
Policy Institute, could argue in 1997 that, "Just as industrial
workers formed the backbone of the New Deal coalition, the party
needs to attract the knowledge workers emerging as the dominant
force in the information economy," the "wired workers"
who use computers.
The elites of the knowledge sector were
more important, however, both as big-dollar contributors and powerful
opinion molders. David Friedman, a fellow at the New America Foundation,
argued in the Los Angeles Times that a "cleansing of working-class
concerns from America's once progressive politics" reflected
the emergence of a "new, fabulously privileged elite-including
Web-site and computer gurus, actors, directors, media magnates
and financial power brokers" who exercised "unparalleled
influence" over mainstream liberalism. As chapter 6 has discussed,
they were not simply a cultural elite but an important economic
elite frequently at loggerheads with the ordinary, nonprofessional
workforces of their industries.
Thomas Ferguson, an expert on political
fundraising, identified telecommunications as the industry that
stood out in its 1996 support for Bill Clinton. This commitment,
he explained, congealed around influencing what became the high-stakes
Telecommunications Act of 1996: "For years, Hollywood, network
and cable television, book publishers, news concerns, radio stations,
computer and software makers and phone companies had all been
making vast sums of money as individual entities. By 1993, however,
changes in technology and regulatory practice were bringing these
industries together at an explosive pace, and almost everyone
wanted legal rights to get into everyone else's business."
Besides these ties to a specific, hugely
wealthy economic sector, the need of Democratic candidates for
large-scale campaign funding had its own profound influence. "Unfortunately,
we've been cowed into the position of not sticking up for working
people," one Democratic strategist told the Philadelphia
Inquirer in 1995, "because we've been looking increasingly
to wealthy interests in order to fund our campaigns. You end up
spending time with wealthy people who say 'Let's not make this
a class thing.'" That many, if not most, Democratic-connected
lawyers, consultants, and lobbyists in Washington also worked
on behalf of corporations, trade associations, and the wealthy
bolstered the reorientation.
The larger pressure, however, arose from
the underlying partial transformation of the Democrats into the
party of a wealthy cultural and technological elite ...
p344
Federal publication in 1966 of the first Social Indicators was
followed in 1967 by Minnesota senator Walter Mondale's proposal
for a Council of Social Advisers to be on a par with the Council
of Economic Advisers. Both projects soon drowned in the public's
disillusionment with experiments like the War against Poverty,
school busing, and rent subsidies as well as the underlying skepticism
of Republican presidents. The Nixon administration turned the
next (1974) volume of Social Indicators into a neutral chartbook.
In 1981 the Reagan administration discontinued publication altogether.
Republican policy intellectuals committed to a market emphasis
generally distrusted social yardsticks, which had sometimes been
abused.
The serious revival of interest in social
indicators in the late 1980s and early 1990s reflected concern
over the Reagan era's rising inequality and seemingly shrinking
social safety net. The Index of Social Health was begun in 1987
by the Fordham (University) Institute for Innovation in Social
Policy under director Marc Miringoff. Of its sixteen criteria,
half were economic, ranging from wages, unemployment, and health
coverage to child poverty. The others were noneconomic, including
infant mortality, high school dropout rates, violent crime, and
teenage drug use. From a peak of 76.9 in 1973, the index fell
to 40 in 1986 and 38 in 1993, rising slightly to 43 in 1996 and
46 in 1999 ...
A second index, quite different in its
mechanics, was the Genuine Progress Indicator, begun in 1994 by
San Francisco-based Redefining Progress. In many ways this was
an alternative gross domestic product calculus in which unproductive
activities counted in official-defined "growth"-the
cost of commuting, environmental burdens, growth that made incomes
more unequal, foreign borrowing, family outlays made to cope with
ill-health and so on-were reentered as minuses. On the other side
of the ledger, activities not hitherto counted in the official
gross product-housework, for example were added in as pluses.
Surprisingly, the trend, at least, of
the Genuine Progress Indicator almost paralleled the Index of
Social Health. Both rose with the upwardmoving gross domestic
product through the early seventies. Then as per capita GDP kept
rising, the indicator, like the index, flattened and turned down.
Interestingly, the same 1970s downturn occurred in two other less
recognized chartings: the Index of Leading Cultural Indicators
drawn up by former education secretary William Bennett, and the
Index of Sustainable Economic Welfare, an environmentally centered
measurement conducted by University of Maryland economist Herman
Daly. Obviously, some things were going wrong.
The various samplers agreed less on the
whys and wherefores than over the decline. Fordham's Miringoff
suggested the loss of well-paying bluecollar jobs might be to
blame. However, both the timing of the divergence from mid-to-late
seventies and the particular weaknesses demonstrated in Fordham's
international social benchmarks by the more individualistic, capitalist
English-speaking nations suggested an additional influence: the
de-emphasis in the U.S. and Britain of social and environmental
criteria and the effects of a triumphant conservatism loosely
committed to markets, globalization, Darwinism, and distrust of
non-economic criteria.
Indeed, as we have seen, the notion of
an ebb barely hides in a half-dozen economic indices. Besides
manufacturing, current account deficit, wage and household debt
numbers, the Department of Labor admits that if part-timers wanting
more work and those wanting jobs but lacking necessary transportation
or child care were included, the unemployment level of 2000 would
have been twice the official 5.5 million total, or some twelve
million. The failure to count as unemployed older men who dropped
out of the workforce in large numbers during the last quarter
of the twentieth century also kept the jobless numbers down.
According to critics, definitions of poverty
in the United States have served as much to hide the problem as
to profile it. The Census Bureau, doubting the adequacy of the
established-and relatively reassuring- poverty definition, recommended
raising the household threshold to $19,500 a year, which would
have left 46 million Americans short in 2000.
Miringoff, in his 1999 volume The Social
Health of the Nation, also included revealing late-1990s individual
rankings of the Western industrial nations for over two-thirds
of his sixteen yardsticks. What these show is that in inequality
measurements, the English-speaking nations, with their greater
emphasis on markets and individualism, invariably led. In the
percentage of poverty among those over sixty-five, the U.S., Australia,
and Britain were the top three. For child poverty, the U.S., Britain,
Australia, Canada, and Ireland were the five nations where it
was highest. In the percentage of those finishing high school,
the U.S. ranked lowest; and in overall inequality, the (negative)
ranks were as follows: U.S. (1), Ireland (2), Australia (4), Britain
(6), and Canada (8).
In rankings for other facets of the perils
of the unfittest, the highest rates of youth homicide came in
the U.S., Northern Ireland, New Zealand, Canada, Israel, Switzerland,
and Australia. With respect to wage levels, such was the relative
downward pressure since the seventies in the English-speaking
countries that six-the U.S., Canada, Australia, Britain, Ireland,
and New Zealand-were in the bottom eleven. The top eleven nations
were all Continental European. It is hard not to conclude that
the other English-speaking nations, sharing many of the benefits
of U.S. financial and technological prowess, also share some of
the accompanying inegalitarian economic and social trendlines.
Parenthetically, university and public
health researchers in Britain and the United States also began
to report during the 1990s that health and life expectancy were
better in states, metropolitan areas, and other jurisdictions
with greater community-mindedness and more egalitarian income
distributions. One survey, done in 1998 by two researchers at
Harvard's School of Public Health, found that among 282 metropolitan
areas, mortality rates were more closely linked to relative than
absolute income, with rising inequality meaning higher mortality.
Their thesis: that erosion of trust or "social capital"
may explain inequality's influence on health.
The United States of the millennium, caught
up in the glories of markets and globalization, was scarcely more
open to these debates than the Britain of 1900.
p347
Charles Kindleberger, 1994
... Hitler overstretched; Napoleon overstretched.
In fact, in The Theory of Moral Sentiments, Adam Smith said that
most of the world's troubles come from somebody not knowing when
to stop and be content.
p361
The top 1 percent pocketed 42 percent of the stock market gains
between 1989 and 1997, while the top 10 percent of the population
took 86 percent.
p362
In 1995, although statistics showed 40 percent of Americans owning
stock directly or through pension funds, mutual funds, or 401(k)
plans, over half had only a minor involvement, often worth less
than their cars. One study by M.I.T. economist James Poterba showed
that 71 percent of families individually owned no shares or held
less than $2,000 worth.
Economist Wolff calculated that between
1989 and 1997 the average stockholdings of the middle quintile,
adjusted for inflation, doubled from $4,000 to $8,000, but their
net worth declined because of taking on debt. Estimates for 1998
and 1999 saw the dollar value of shareholdings climb higher among
the 50th to 90th percentiles, but these were soon reduced by the
2000-2001 bear market.
... As the mania crested, household discretionary
portfolios regained and then surpassed their 1960s commitment
to equities and equity mutual funds-at which point, the bubble
popped.
Comparisons with the 1950s and 1960s are
difficult because the earlier stock ownership data did not include
those who owned stocks through pensions funds, retirement funds,
or mutual funds. In his 1962 book Wealth and Power in America,
Gabriel Kolko argued that even when the total number of shareholders
increased, that made little difference to the concentration at
the top, in which 1 to 2 percent of them owned 40 to 60 percent
of the privately held stock. The 12.5 million shareowners of 1959,
he said, actually represented a considerably smaller ratio of
the total U.S. population than the 9 to 11 million shareholders
of 1930. Sour memories lingered.
Wealth
and Democracy
Index
of Website
Home Page