The Emergence of Modern Politics
excerpted from the book
The New Progressive Era
Toward a Fair and Deliberative
Democracy
by Peter Levine
Rowman and Littlefield, 2000,
paper
p45
... the credit for ending segregation belongs not to Progressive
reformers or other federal politicians but primarily to Southern
blacks. Civil rights initiatives succeeded only after valiant,
well-publicized grassroots struggles had provoked white racist
violence that embarrassed the national government. For example,
the Civil Rights Act of 1964 passed when Bull Connor trained his
fire hoses on black children in Birmingham; the Voting Rights
Act passed when Colonel Al Lingo's state troopers beat peaceful
marchers on the Edmund Pettus Bridge near Selma. Furthermore,
legal guarantees of rights meant nothing until civil rights workers
actually registered voters, ran for election, and took office
amid violence. Where the largely white Progressives had failed
to bring democracy to people of color, the black-led civil rights
crusade largely succeeded, using methods of nonviolent resistance.
The ideas that inspired such leaders as
Martin Luther King, Jr., mostly came from sources other than Progressivism.
King, for example, drew on the Exodus story and the Hebrew prophets,
the New Testament, the rhetoric of the abolitionist church, the
long tradition of African-American solidarity and resistance,
and the struggle against European imperialism, especially in India.
p46
[Martin Luther] King [Jr.] ... came to see the Social Gospel doctrine
as naive. He reached this conclusion under the influence of Reinhold
Niebuhr, another theologian who had considered himself a Progressive.
(Indeed, Niebuhr began his political career working on La Follette's
last presidential campaign.) "I became so enamored of [Niebuhr's]
social ethics," King once wrote, "that I almost fell
into the trap of accepting uncritically everything he wrote."
18 Niebuhr took seriously the idea of original sin, believing
that force or greed governed all large-scale human institutions
and that consensus was utopian. Individuals, who were created
in God's image, could be moral in their personal relationships;
but human beings also had to live in society, and no society would
cohere except under threat of force. Niebuhr accused Rauschenbusch
of overestimating the power of moral suasion and "the community-building
capacities of human sympathy." Polities, for Niebuhr, was
largely a clash of economic interests, and society could become
just only if powerful interests were curbed by force.
Despite his "realism," Niebuhr
shared the Progressives' ideal of a democratic society, governed
by discussion rather than coercion. Like his Progressive colleagues,
he thought that the point of a democratic state was to "arbitrate
conflicts from a more impartial perspective than is available
to any party in a given conflict." A true democracy was not
merely a system of private rights but a community in which "rights
and liberties [are] exercised with a higher sense of responsibility
for the common good."' All of this sounded like conventional
Progressivism, but Niebuhr was hard-nosed enough to think that
the struggle for community and justice often required force. For
example, he argued that American whites would never renounce their
privileges without a struggle. However, black Americans faced
very long odds if they resorted to violence; and force had a tendency
to spin out of control. Under these circumstances, Niebuhr advocated
Gandhian methods of nonviolent resistance. Beginning in 1947,
the Civil Rights Movement used just such methods to achieve racial
justice that had eluded the Progressives. Thus King and his colleagues
moved beyond Progressivism by embracing radical, confrontational,
extra-legal means to achieve a Progressive end. Such means might
have frightened reformers like La Follette, but they proved necessary-for
reasons that Niebuhr understood.
The Civil Rights leaders also enriched
the Progressives' ideal of a democratic community. For many Progressives,
the basic goals of reform were negative: to protect the people
against corrupt politicians and predatory special interests. They
knew what they opposed but not exactly what they stood for. La
Follette once wrote: "Mere passive citizenship is not enough."
But the alternative that he favored was a defensive struggle against
anti-democratic forces: "Men must be aggressive for what
is right if government is to be saved from those who are aggressive
for what is wrong."
p49
Looking back at the New Left, it is difficult to see through the
late-60s haze of incense, pot, tear gas, and burning cities. But
if the "Movement" began at any identifiable moment,
it was when Students for a Democratic Society (SDS) published
their Port Huron Statement in 1962. This document popularized
the phrases "new left" and "participatory democracy"
for the decade to come. It was written at a conference organized
by Robert Alan Haber, whose parents had named him after Robert
La Follette, Sr. The SDS itself grew out of the John Dewey Discussion
Society at the University of Michigan. Its founders still thought
in the tradition of Midwestern Progressivism; La Follette could
easily have signed their Statement.
Far from demanding social revolution or
Marxist economic policies, the Port Huron Statement advocated
conventional political reform. The SDS authors claimed that the
seniority system in Congress gave too much power to racist "Dixiecrats."
The major parties were incoherent coalitions, so voters lacked
clear choices on election day. Blacks and migrant workers were
disenfranchised; gerrymandering hurt the cities. Politicians "respond
not to dialogue, but to pressure: and knowing this, the ordinary
citizen feels even greater inclination to shun the political sphere."
An "enormous lobby force, composed predominantly of business
interests, [spends] hundreds of millions each year."
The SDS authors also argued that civil
society needed renewal, in order to remedy the "loneliness,
estrangement, isolation" that "describe the vast distance
between man and man." They opposed big bureaucracies, for,
in a participatory democracy, "decision-making of basic social
consequence [would be] carried on by public groupings." Therefore,
they argued: "Mechanisms of voluntary association must be
created through which political information can be imparted and
political participation encouraged." To counter special interests,
citizens should organize into participatory groups, and the government
should distribute "objective materials on all public issues."
The SDS authors wanted to enlarge the
public sector so that economic activity could be "debated
and planned," which was impossible in a market. But they
wanted this state sector to be truly "public, and not the
arena of a ruling bureaucracy of 'public servants.'" This
would require "steadfast opposition to bureaucratic coagulation."
More important, it would demand "experiments in decentralization."
Although they didn't use his name, they endorsed Wilbur Phillips's
Social Unit Plan for "community decision-making and participation."
From 1962 to 1965, SDS members tried to
put their theory into practice by organizing poor residents of
Northern cities. At the same time, the most radical of the Civil
Rights groups, the Student Nonviolent Coordinating Committee (SNCC),
organized blacks in the rural South. Both groups considered themselves
'nonideological," believing that the people they organized
should set their own political agendas. They saw themselves as
catalysts, not as leaders in the traditional sense. They encouraged
poor people to talk about social issues, taught them political
skills, formed loosely structured organizations, and established
"free spaces"-offices, shelters, and union halls-where
people could meet to talk. Jane Mansbridge recalls, "In the
late 1960s, every major American city and every rural area to
which young people had migrated could claim a host of free schools,
food co-ops, law communes, women's centers, hot lines, and health
clinics organized along 'participatory' lines." For the most
part, they followed "the unwritten rules of unitary democracy:
face-to-face, consensual decision making and the elimination of
all internal distinctions that could encourage or legitimate inequality."
Most of this was happening without SNCC
or SDS, whose organizers had encountered difficulties by the middle
of the decade. Their privileged backgrounds caused them to stand
out uncomfortably in the poor neighborhoods where they worked.
They discovered intimidating obstacles to even modest social change,
and their resistance to authority made them hesitant to adopt
leadership roles. In one extreme example-the SDS "nonproject"
in Hoboken, New Jersey-the "organizers" decided to take
no action beyond finding blue-collar jobs and waiting for the
working class to mobilize itself.
As the sixties progressed, frustrated
SDS members renounced their own Port Huron Statement as "bourgeois"
and began endless debates about the nature of the Marxist revolution
to come. However, parts of the statement were implemented when
Lyndon Johnson began the Great Society initiative in 1964. Johnson
certainly paid no attention to the SDS or SNCC, but ideas about
participatory democracy were in the air, thanks to John Dewey
and the Progressive Settlement Houses, C. Wright Mills and Saul
Alinsky, organized labor and the mainstream Civil Rights organizations,
sociologists like Richard Cloward and Lloyd Ohlin, and the Ford
Foundation. The Kennedy administration had put some of these ideas
into practice when it began a juvenile-delinquency program, but
the Kennedys were more interested in expertise and efficiency
than grassroots democracy. Then urban America started to burn,
and the Johnson administration had to respond somehow to the new
militancy of Northern blacks. In 1964, Johnson announced a War
on Poverty.
The main weapon in this "war"
was the Economic Opportunity Act, which introduced the idea of
"community action" to end poverty in the United States.
A community action program had to be "developed, conducted,
and administered with the maximum feasible participation of the
residents of the areas and members of the groups served."
Johnson explained: "This program asks men and women throughout
the country to prepare long-range plans for the attack on poverty
in their own local communities. These are not plans prepared in
Washington and imposed upon hundreds of different situations.
They are based on the fact that local citizens best understand
their own problems and know best how to deal with those problems.
In the same vein, the Model Cities bill
of 1966 required "widespread citizen participation."
Under the authority of these statutes, the federal government
began Head Start, the Public Health Service, the Legal Services
program, public housing and urban renewal assistance, community
mental health centers, the New Careers Program, and scores of
other welfare initiatives. These new programs, plus much of the
existing welfare state, came under the "maximum feasible
participation" mandate. Community Action Associations, or
CAAs, were established in poor and disadvantaged areas-theoretically,
to oversee all federal services and to give citizens opportunities
to influence the welfare bureaucracy. After eighteen months, 1,000
CAAs had begun operation and were experimenting busily. They created
citizens' advisory committees; held open hearings; organized "unions"
of people who received government services; established community
corporations with actual control over services; developed poor
peoples' political skills; and otherwise tried to generate an
"urban community based on small, self-contained, self-maintaining,
self-directing neighborhoods."
The idea of community action quickly ran
into trouble. Many local politicians, threatened by direct federal
intervention in their cities, began making patronage appointments
to CAA boards. Often, when politicians or bureaucrats selected
community representatives, residents came to distrust the entire
process. Some local politicians actually preferred to hold elections,
since independent candidates lacked the money necessary to wage
effective campaigns. In general, turnout in CAA elections was
low, and professional politicians controlled the outcome. For
example, federal officials set up 154 polling places in the Watts
area of Los Angeles, chartered 25 buses, and mailed 10O,000 leaflets
to residents, but fewer than 1 percent of eligible voters participated,
at a cost of $22.94 a vote. When Los Angeles stopped trying to
achieve community representation, the federal grants kept flowing.
Meanwhile, "poor," "citizen," and "community"
all gradually became code-words for "black." Therefore,
even well-meaning white politicians assumed that they could fulfill
the community participation mandate if they merely talked to established
African-American leaders, such as the local head of the NAACP.
Perhaps no one in power had ever meant
to cede real authority to welfare recipients. Johnson's promise
of broad public participation may have been a rhetorical flourish.
However, the promise itself had a powerful motivational effect.
Across the country, poor people demanded the right to participate
in CAA governance. In at least twenty cities, they gained control
of their local boards, usually after a bitter struggle. Once aroused,
they took the same fight to school boards, police oversight bodies,
city counsels, and state legislatures. A whole generation of poor
and minority leaders matured during the War on Poverty-although
not exclusively because of it.
Through Neighborhood Legal Services, they
filed class-action lawsuits on behalf of poor people. They demanded
participation not only in government agencies, but also in all
the bureaucracies they encountered, including colleges, hospitals,
foundations, and the United Way. CAA directors hired as many as
180,000 workers and created thousands of independent organizations
to manage federal programs or to agitate politically; most of
these groups were staffed by black people from poor backgrounds.
Community-action workers duplicated some of the habits of the
old political machines, dispensing patronage and trading favors.
However, the beneficiaries were people who had never been able
to participate in politics before. In many cases, CAA directors
gradually abandoned their militant styles and became traditional
politicians or bureaucrats during the 1970s. Radical critics complained
that these minority leaders had been "coopted into the system,"
and leftist historians have since echoed that complaint. It is
true that no revolution occurred, but War on Poverty workers organized
themselves into insurgent political movements that captured City
Hall in Detroit, Atlanta, Cincinnati, Los Angeles, and many smaller
communities. Majority rule in the nation's great cities was no
small achievement.
During the Kennedy administration, the
first experiments in community action were deliberately designed
to encourage political reform. The idea was to give federal money
to grassroots groups of poor people, bypassing state and local
governments that were controlled by affluent majorities or by
white-ethnic political machines. Once poor people became organized
and politically "competent," they would begin to vote,
run for office, and otherwise force their local governments to
represent them. SDS, SNCC, and other private organizations on
the Left also tried initially to organize the poor so that they
could gain more influence over official government institutions;
participatory democracy was supposed to complement and improve
representative democracy, not replace it.
But mayors and governors were predictably
upset when federal money began supporting grassroots institutions
controlled by independent black leaders. They fought back, winning
some battles and losing others. As the conflict grew bitter-even
violent, everyone had to take sides. Johnson, the epitome of a
professional politician, lined up with local elected officials.
He once asked Sargent Shriver, the War on Poverty's general, whether
his office was being "run by a bunch of kooks, commies, and
queers." In fact, many poverty activists had completely lost
interest in traditional political reform, arguing-as the popular
slogan put it-that "democracy is in the streets." They
now believed that authentic democracy was participatory, not representative.
The democratic spirit was alive on picket lines, in union halls,
in communes, even during riots-but not in the dry business of
legislation and administration. New Leftists instinctively resisted
all kinds of formal authority. In 1971, Crosby, Stills, and Nash
sang in protest against the mayor of Chicago, Richard J. Daley:
"Rules and regulations, who needs them? Throw 'em out the
door!"
This attitude was not necessarily democratic.
After all, a standard theory of democracy holds that citizens
are best represented by elected officials who sit in deliberative
bodies. Nor is it only the Left that resists state authority-Ronald
Reagan and Newt Gingrich have also denounced regulation, bureaucracy,
and government intervention. It was true in 1964, as it is today,
that local governments ignored some of their citizens, but the
proper response was to enfranchise nonvoters, redraw electoral
districts, delegate power to local elected bodies, experiment
with proportional representation, and revamp campaign-finance
systems. Unless local governments were reformed, they would inevitably
try to suppress poor people. If radicals succeeded in bypassing
or subverting government, then citizens would lose their chance
to be represented democratically. Ironically, however, the most
lasting impact of the War on Poverty was fairly conventional political
reform. Poor people, especially African Americans, gained political
skills through community action and then demanded changes in state
and local politics. As a result, institutions from school boards
to state legislatures became more open, fair, and representative.
The Great Society embodied a liberal social
philosophy: it redistributed wealth from the rich to the poor
and created new positive economic rights or entitlements. These
values did not follow from pure Progressive principles. A democratic
people may decide collectively to reject liberalism, as many Americans
had by 1980. However, there was more to the Great Society than
liberal economics: it also strengthened democracy by building
fair, participatory, deliberative institutions at the local level.
This aspect of the War on Poverty followed from classic Progressive
ideas about citizenship and self-government. An independent study
published in 1970 took into account all the failures of community
action but concluded: "Federally supported programs have
created the ground for a remarkably rich, complex, exciting communal
life for a growing number of people." When modern conservatives
attack "big government," they overlook this aspect of
the Great Society-as do many liberals when they defend the welfare
state. By themselves, the experiments in participatory democracy
were not hugely expensive, so they could be implemented by fiscal
conservatives of either party. At a minimum, the War on Poverty
provides a worthy point of departure for people who hope to involve
more citizens in self-government.
p56
In the early 1970s, public-interest groups wielded considerable
power in Washington, just as consumer advocates had influenced
Congress around 1912. Nearly 100,000 households gave "at
least $70 a year to three or more of the following: Common Cause,
Public Citizen, ACLU, public television and public radio, and
environmental lobbying groups." Senator Abraham Ribikoff
(D-CT) observed, "instead of the big lobbies of the major
corporations dominating the hearings process, you have had practically
every committee in Congress according 'equal time' to public interest
people." In 1969-72, David Vogel writes, "Congress enacted
the most progressive tax bill in the postwar period, transferred
the primary authority for the regulation of both pollution and
occupational health and safety from the states to the federal
government, established the Consumer Product
Safety Administration, and banned the
advertising of cigarettes from radio and television." Most
of these changes were advocated by "Nader's Raiders,"
the hundreds of volunteers and lawyers who staffed the Center
for the Study of Responsive Law.
But the dominance of public-interest groups
could not last for long. Vogel writes: "It took business
about seven years to rediscover how to win in Washington."
With their enormous advantages of wealth and discipline, they
appropriated the tactics of the public-interest movement, including
the "sponsorship of research studies to influence elite opinion,
the attention to the media as a way of changing public attitudes,
the development of techniques of grassroots organizing to mobilize
supporters in congressional districts, and the use of ad hoc coalitions
to maximize political influence." Industry lobbyists were
as successful in 1978-81 as public-interest activists had been
a decade before.
For every Common Cause or MALDEF, there
were now scores of trade groups, professional associations, and
corporate PACs, each with a large budget. By 198O, public-interest
groups were able to attend only half of all federal regulatory
proceedings, and when they were present, they constituted less
than 10 percent of the witness lists. There is no evidence that
they have gained influence since 198O, but their enemies have.
Today, almost one-fourth of the 15 million businesses in America
belong "to some kind of business, professional, or trade
association." Five of the richest counties in America are
Washington suburbs, in part because of all the legal, political,
and technical experts who are employed by economic interests.
Meanwhile, conservative think tanks have increased their budgets
as much as tenfold, their research supported by large corporate
grants.
p57
In the interest group liberal regime of 1940 or 196O, there was
little deliberation about the common good; political strength
and money usually carried the day. Nevertheless, workers had considerable
influence, because the Democratic Party and labor unions were
powerful negotiating blocs. By and large, rank-and-file members
of these huge organizations trusted their leaders to tell them
how to vote and when to strike. Although this trust could be misplaced,
it was often salutary. To acquire political information is difficult,
time-consuming, and expensive, so most people don't participate
at all unless they are guided by trusted institutions.
One set of institutions, political parties,
suffered when the campaign-reform and civil-service bills of the
early 1970s struck at their main sources of power: fundraising
and patronage. Meanwhile, unions lost members rapidly as a result
of mechanization, foreign competition, and weak labor laws. Workers
and middle-class consumers did gain the support of lobbies such
as Common Cause and Public Citizen, but these groups had far less
power than the old party structures. In 1994, just 2.8 percent
of the population said that they were members of "some group
like the League of Women Voters, or some other group which is
interested in better government." By contrast, almost one-third
of nonagricultural workers had belonged to unions in 1953, and
47 percent of voting-age Americans had identified themselves as
Democrats. The rise of organizations like Public Citizen could
hardly compensate for a 50-percent drop in union membership or
a 25 percent decline in support for the Democratic Party. Given
their low levels of public support, the new representatives of
workers, citizens, and consumers did not have much clout.
Finally, the Progressive reforms of the
1970s failed because they did not complete the job that reformers
set themselves: getting money out of politics. Congress exempted
itself from the system of partial public financing that it imposed
on presidential candidates. Also, private groups could establish
political action committees, or PACs, that could collect money
and pass it on to candidates. This meant that corporations could
make legal campaign contributions for the first time since the
Progressive Era, albeit using PACs as intermediaries. To make
matters worse, the Supreme Court overturned much of FECA in its
Buckley v Valeo decision of 1976. The Court found that campaign
spending and political contributions were forms of expression
that enjoyed First Amendment protection. Therefore, a limit on
campaign spending would violate constitutional rights. Citizens
also had the right, according to Buckley to spend unlimited sums
on their own campaigns. However, the Court upheld two kinds of
limits: on the amount that each person or PAC could contribute
to any candidate, and on the total annual contributions by each
citizen or PAC. The Court found that these provisions were justified,
since they prevented corruption and the appearance of corruption
without unduly reducing free expression.'
When the dust settled, presidential campaigns
were covered by a stringent set of rules, but congressional candidates
had to contend only with disclosure provisions and contribution
limits: they could raise and spend as much as they wanted. Since
special-interest money could no longer flow into presidential
races, contributors formed PACs and turned their attention to
congressional campaigns. Between 1974 and 1976, there was a five-fold
increase in the number of business PACs. Unions also increased
their contributions, but at a more modest rate: from $6.3 million
to $8.3 million.
The new campaign-finance regime struck
a final, fatal blow at political machines. Everything that party
bosses had done to accumulate power had cost them money, which
they had raised from special interests. With stringent limits
on party fundraising, the earmarks of the old system quickly disappeared:
gone were most of the old smoky back rooms, party hacks, ward
heelers, powerful partisan clubs, and slush funds. In 1950, city
bosses had hand-picked congressmen, and national party leaders
had chosen their presidential nominees. By l990, there were hardly
any bosses left, and party chairs were figureheads. However, candidates
could still raise money from private sources and spend it in the
marketplace. As a result, the traditional cast of political characters
was soon replaced by a new one: PAC directors, political consultants,
independent pollsters, fundraising experts, and incumbent politicians
with huge personal war chests.
I will return to a detailed critique of
the new system in chapter 4, but its unsavory features are not
hard to spot. Above all, money still undermined the basic principle
of fairness. Organized workers and corporations both wielded substantial
influence through their PACs. In 1974, Ben Albert, an AFL-CIO
public relations director, said: "we are having no problem
with the law. We function very comfortably with it." However,
consumers, tenants, and patients had no PACs, so they had very
little clout compared to manufacturers, landlords, and hospitals.
The poor and unemployed certainly had no way to make large campaign
contributions. Finally, rich individuals, unlike unionized workers,
could make personal contributions to supplement business PAC money.
Progressives, faced with this situation,
would have demanded basic reform, aimed at replacing all large
private contributions with small donations and public matching
funds. However, the Watergate Babies had learned to thrive under
the new system. They enjoyed reelection rates of close to 100
percent, in part because of a huge advantage in fundraising. Starting
in the early 1980s, they became the chief defenders of the status
quo. Led by Representative Tony Coehlo (D-CA), the head of the
Democratic Congressional Campaign Committee, House Democrats approached
business with the following argument. They pointed out that they
were the majority party, having controlled the House for all but
a few of the past fifty years. Therefore, business was wasting
its money giving to Republicans. Business PACs would be foolish
not to contribute to Democrats as a way of increasing their access,
goodwill, and influence. The PACs complied, and money gradually
eroded the lines of ideological demarcation, precluding real debate
about many economic issues. As Robert Reich wrote before he became
secretary of labor:
The Democrats ... lost their identity
not because Americans became more respectful of wealth and power
or more convinced trickle-down economics would actually work (polls
show widespread opposition to capital gains breaks for the rich),
but because Democrats became dependent on the rich to finance
their campaigns.... It Is difficult to represent the little fellow
when the big fellow pays the tab.... Democrats have come to sound
like Republicans because they rely on the same funders to make
the same contacts as the GOP.
To make matters worse, after 1984 private
money returned to presidential campaigns with a vengeance, thanks
to both parties' exploitation of a loophole in FECA. Starting
in 1976, general-election candidates who received public funding
were supposed to accept no private money at all. But the Federal
Election Commission ruled that individuals and PACs could contribute
to parties, which could spend their money on generic, "party-building"
activities that would benefit their candidates. By the mid-nineties,
this so-called soft money, laundered through party organizations,
flowed at the rate of hundreds of millions of dollars in every
election cycle.
p61
... congressional Democrats resisted reform, clinging to their
privileges, and the Clinton administration failed to challenge
them. The administration refused to disclose the size of the intelligence
budget and delayed releasing classified documents. Campaign-finance
reform, lobby regulation, and new ethics rules all died in Congress.
Clinton's first chair of the Democratic National Committee (DNC),
David Wilhelm, tried to raise money in a populist fashion, soliciting
small donations from a wide base. He raised $9 million in contributions
of less than $200 each, but the fundraising campaign cost the
committee $8 million. Shaken by the Democrats' defeat in the 1994
House elections and the "Harry and Louise" commercials
that had helped to sink his health-reform bill, Clinton listened
to his consultant, Dick Morris. Morris planned a massive polling
and broadcast campaign, which would cost the DNC $1.5 million
every week. But the party had almost no funds. Top administration
officials scrambled to raise money, using disreputable intermediaries,
offering nights in the Lincoln Bedroom, and accepting illegal
contributions from foreign donors.
In 1994, the Democrats finally lost control
of the House, not because they had failed to pass political reform,
but because they had achieved little meaningful change of any
kind. This failure, in turn, resulted from the sordid political
system that congressional Democrats had permitted to flourish.
Moreover, Republicans successfully portrayed the Democratic majority
as corrupt, mostly by dwelling on relatively trivial issues such
as the House Bank scandal. By refusing to change their ways, the
Democrats left the Republican charges unanswered. Turnout among
core Democratic constituencies was extremely low in 1994, because
poor people and minorities saw nothing worth defending in Washington.
However wealthy people voted in unprecedentedly high numbers,
perhaps fearful of the I Democrats' health agenda. The result
was a stunning victory for Representative Newt Gingrich and his
House Republican acolytes
p63
... Republicans began a wholesale transfer of federal programs
to the states. Most prominently, they replaced most federal welfare
entitlements with block grants. They had economic motivations
for these changes, which William Kristol described candidly. Block
grants, he explained, were not the ultimate goal, since they might
make "state and local governments . . . ever more dependent
extensions of the federal octopus." Instead, conservatives
wanted "real federalism, understood as part of a general
program of relimiting government." This meant transferring
power from the states to private citizens and corporations, once
the federal government had "devolved" its authority
to the states.
Thus, for conservatives, devolution was
not just a way to reorganize government functions, shifting them
from one level to another in the name of efficiency or accountability.
It was rather a tactic in their war against the state. For fifty
years, voters had supported a large federal government that, according
to Kristol, had become self-perpetuating and "pathological."
Conservative candidates had often won national elections, but
they seemed unable to destroy this beast. In fact, an assertive
national government had remained broadly popular: for example,
voters revolted whenever politicians talked of trimming Medicare
and Social Security. But Kristol wanted to kill the welfare state
once and for all by changing the rules of politics. Indeed, this
was his justification for the whole Republican reform agenda,
including "a balanced budget amendment, term limits, tax
and spending limitation at several levels of government, . . .
and the privatization of government functions.''
But why would devolution undermine the
welfare state? Why wouldn't each state and locality ultimately
increase its taxes to make up for reduced federal aid? In short,
why would giving power to the states produce the laissez-faire
economic policy beloved of conservatives? Kristol argued that
the federal government was unpopular but entrenched-that liberals
won reelection only because powerful interest groups supported
them. If the federal system were destroyed, no new welfare state
would arise to replace it. This argument ignored the deep and
abiding popularity of middle-class entitlements. But Kristol did
not state another, more plausible argument. The smaller the unit
of government, the less power it has to distribute wealth from
rich to poor. Many affluent citizens already live across jurisdictional
lines from the people who need government services the most. Those
who still reside in states with large poor populations and traditions
of social welfare would be free to move away if federal taxes
dropped and states tried to pick up the burden. It is no accident
that state income taxes are much less progressive than the federal
system; indeed, the poorest fifth of the population pays 12.5
percent of their income in state and local taxes, whereas the
richest percentile pays only 7.9 percent.
Thus there were conservative economic
reasons to favor devolution. But transferring power to the states
also has a Progressive rationale. State governments, some people
believe, are "closer to the people." State legislators
represent smaller districts than federal legislators; state capitals
are physically closer than Washington; and state governments are
smaller and easier to understand than the federal bureaucracy.
Therefore, a welfare program administered by the states might
be more accountable than the federal program it replaced. On the
other hand, the federal government undergoes much more scrutiny
than state governments do. The Washington press corps far outnumbers
the reporters in any state capital. Perhaps, as power flows to
the states, they will receive more critical attention, but it
is inherently difficult to keep track of fifty separate governments.
National television cannot begin to do the job; neither can news
magazines or the New York Times. Thus it is by no means certain
that devolution to state governments will produce more accountable
politics. What is certain is that poor areas will receive less
aid from wealthy ones.
The
New Progressive Era
Index
of Website
Home Page