The Decade of Perpetual Crises,
1969 through the 1970s
Part I
excerpted from the book
Confronting the Third World
United States Foreign Policy 1945-1980
by Gabriel Kolko
Pantheon Books,1988
p210
The American role in the Third World under Nixon represented a
continuation of those of his predecessors save in one important
regard, and it more than undercut the initial constraining premises
of the original Nixon Doctrine. Nixon was convinced that the Vietnam
War could be won as much through a diplomatic offensive to gain
Soviet, and later Chinese, cooperation as any other factor, and
his unwavering devotion to this strategy even as it was largely
failing led the Administration to believe it could also apply
this ambitious global effort to resolve innumerable essentially
unrelated issues throughout the Third World. More than any other
postwar president, Nixon and his devoted assistant Kissinger treated
events and movements in the Third World as mere pawns of a giant
Cold War struggle, without concern for their local causes or their
real autonomy.
p217
Chile and the End of Illusions
Chile in many regards resembled the other
Latin nations seeking to develop economically, and it posed the
same problems for the United States as well. Import-substitute
strategies had won support from a rural elite as well as urban
middle classes that had both blood and business ties to each other,
and the state was assigned an important role in implementing them.
Unlike Brazil, however, the effort was less successful in this
much smaller country, in part because Yankee-owned firms solidly
dominated its copper exports, which earned the large majority
of its foreign exchange. U.S. relations with Chile, therefore,
operated within a context in which American interests conflicted
with those of most of the Chilean political parties. Moreover,
unlike Brazil, the Left was far more powerful, partially because
of one of the most inequitable land distributions in the hemisphere,
and in 1958 the Socialist candidate, Salvador Allende Gossens,
narrowly missed defeating conservative Jorge Alessandri for the
presidency. After Cuba, Chile by the early 1960s was the one Latin
nation most likely to break totally with U.S. hegemony.
Chile's upper and middle classes also
possessed the ambiguities that marked conservative nationalist
reform movements elsewhere, and their addiction to imports essential
for their life-style caused post-1955 governments to run up debts
and borrow heavily, periodically allowing the IMF to impose austerity
programs requiring more emphasis on exports and reduced internal
economic development programs. Politically anti-United States,
the elite vacillated between collaboration and hostility toward
it. Washington, on the other hand, had to weigh its fear of the
Left against its opposition to a conservative nationalism that
was the most immediate threat to its interests. Chilean-American
relations until 1970 reflected all these conflicting crosscurrents.
Chile received far more aid and loans
on a per capita basis than any other Latin nation during the decade
of the 1960s, most of it as part of an effort to elect Christian
Democrat Eduardo Frei in the September 1964 presidential race.
The ClA's direct support for his campaign cost three million dollars,
though some estimates run far higher. The United States turned
to Frei in 1964 at a time when it preferred officers elsewhere
primarily because the Chilean military had been relatively apolitical
since 1933, proudly contrasting its professionalism to that of
its neighbors. At the same time that Washington chose to support
Frei as the man most likely to accommodate its interests yet introduce
simultaneously sufficient reform to preempt the Left, it also
resolved to politicize Chile's officers, especially regarding
the Communist threat within Chile itself, and they became the
focus of special strategic intelligence courses organized for
them in the U.S. Army's Canal Zone training school. Until that
transformation occurred, however, Washington was
compelled to rely on civilian politicians-and
it was never happy with the results.
Frei became a problem for the United States
partially because of his contradictory program, which sought to
introduce a measure of reform along with development in the context
of collaboration with foreign investment, which he saw as essential
as long as copper required export outlets; but Frei's effort to
accomplish essentially irreconcilable goals soon increasingly
alienated everyone. Two U.S. companies, Anaconda and Kennecott
Copper, accounted for 90 percent of Chile's output, and the only
way Frei could raise funds for his programs without borrowing
was to force up the price of copper and obtain a greater share
of its profits. Frei attempted against stout U.S. resistance to
increase the price of copper in 1965 by two cents a pound, to
thirty-eight cents, and Washington regarded the matter with "most
serious concern" and immediately linked future loans and
aid to the dispute. In fact Frei wanted greater trade revenues
as well as aid, and he guaranteed the United States a hundred
thousand tons of copper a year at thirty-six cents a pound even
as the world price, under Vietnam War-induced scarcity, reached
over twice that. With aid linked to prices, U.S. officials calculated
that the savings to U.S. buyers equaled the value of the surplus
food it was dumping in Chile. It was not a situation conducive
to Frei remaining sympathetic to Yankee advice or interests, yet
while his concessions to the United States alienated the radicals
in his own party, his impositions on the Americans managed to
deepen their mistrust of him, for in his own way, Frei was an
economic nationalist.
Frei sought to attain all his social goals
without breaking with the United States when he introduced a plan
in 1966 to "Chileanize" the copper industry. Essentially
an effort to compel the companies to invest and nearly double
their output, it increased their revenues along with their taxes.
The state purchased a 51 percent interest in the two U.S. firms,
but the Americans were permitted to manage them both at home and
overseas, a situation that caused their profits to rise astronomically
while Chile's income increased sharply also. At the same time,
following an economic downturn that began in 1967, the IMF forced
an austerity program upon Chile that required a postponement of
land reform and alienated both those to Frei's right and left
who objected to such kind treatment of U.S. firms while their
needs were either being attacked or neglected. Frei's economic
program had become confused and inconsistent, still subject to
American control, and the elite began to send its money abroad.
Even Washington found Frei's support for its Vietnam policy more
than offset by his open opposition to it on all Latin issues,
ranging from Peru's and Bolivia's measures against U.S. firms
to its invasion of the Dominican Republic and diplomatic isolation
of Cuba. In 1969 with his party now well to the left of him, Frei
tried to return to total nationalization after the Christian Democrats
lost heavily in the 1969 congressional elections. It was Frei
who nationalized Anaconda in June 1969, but it was too late. The
radical wing took over his party.
In 1969 the Nixon Administration was therefore
faced with a possible political defeat in Chile regardless of
whether the Left, which now emerged as an Allende-led Popular
Unity coalition of Socialists, Communists, and others, won or
not. Indeed, the White House's hostility toward the Christian
Democrats, who nominated Radomiro Tomic for the September 4, 1970,
presidential election on a program of total, immediate copper
nationalization, was no less intense. It was obvious that it could
lose everything unless it could affect the election outcome.
The United States' deep involvement in
the 1970 election was later subjected to massive congressional
investigations, so a brief outline here is sufficient. While the
U.S. private investments of eight hundred million dollars were
surely as important as any reason for its efforts, it was by no
means the only one. It was wholly impossible for the Nixon Administration
to accept either a leftist or a nationalist victory at the polls.
The former was the more frightful because of geopolitics, visions
of dominos falling throughout the region, credibility, and all
the fixations that had long since become conventional wisdom.
But it was Tomic, above all, with his Catholic and middle-class
backing, who possessed the greatest and therefore the most dangerous
appeal for other nationalist parties in the region and who revealed
how fundamental America's economic interests were in its overall
calculations. The CIA did not think Chile's loss to either would
affect the United States' world military position. What was at
stake was both economic and psychological, and the White House
was prepared to go to great lengths to hold on to Chile.
The United States moved in three directions:
first, it sought to influence the election's outcome via money;
next, it tried to have Allende assassinated; and last, it attempted
to convince the military to overthrow Allende. These efforts were
more or less sequential. The first had been employed with Frei
and it was a standard procedure throughout the world, while the
last two were frequently utilized as well. "There is a gray
area between military intervention and formal diplomacy,"
Kissinger later characterized this effort, "where our democracy
is forced to compete against groups inimical to it." Frustrating
the outcome of a free election was a common way of doing so.
The U.S. government itself gave money
for anti-Allende activity designed to win the election for Alessandri,
the Conservative. The sums actually committed were not large,
and probably less than went to Frei in 1964. American firms in
Chile, led by ITT, also made comparable contributions, but Washington
had convinced itself that Alessandri would win and that huge amounts
were unnecessary. When Allende won a plurality of votes, a common
event in Chile that meant the Congress would elect him to power
fifty days later, the infuriated White House then turned to the
assassination and coup options.
The murder of Allende was too difficult
for the CIA to organize, though they paid money to at least one
assassin who managed only to get himself arrested. More serious
was its effort to urge the military to take power, a thought it
had been cultivating since 1964 and that conformed to American
practices elsewhere. Here the main obstacle was the commander
in chief of the army, General Rene Schneider, who was a strict
constitutionalist and represented the old army traditions. The
CIA both armed and paid a small band of rightist officers to kidnap
him, and cooperative officers were assured "of continued
American military assistance if they moved," in Kissinger's
words, to overthrow Allende, but after failing in two efforts,
they simply killed Schneider. The United States later claimed
it was done without their weapons or authorization, but that it
accomplished the task of eliminating a man they thought a major
obstruction cannot be denied. Schneider's assassination did not
stimulate a coup; rather, those senior officers who had shown
interest now pulled back, and an uncontested congressional election
made Allende president on October 24. Allende's first major action
was to complete the nationalization of all foreign copper companies,
a policy Tomic also endorsed. Chile now had a democratically elected
Marxist government pledged to create a "republic of the working
class." It was the first in the hemisphere's history.
The White House's policy, while it assigned
a major role to covert efforts, was essentially to reinforce its
relationship to the military and wait for it to act. As long as
the military had a monopoly of the arms, the Allende government's
freedom to act was sharply constrained. Meanwhile, the United
States turned to economic pressures with the goal, as Nixon jotted
in his notes, to "make the economy scream." "Not
a nut or bolt will be allowed to reach Chile under Allende,"
the U.S. ambassador had warned Frei. "Once Allende comes
to power we shall do all within our power to condemn Chile and
the Chileans to utmost deprivation and poverty...."9 A policy
of implacable hostility became official policy. All U.S. aid or
loans were cut to a trickle, save insofar as they helped the military,
and Washington successfully blocked all new official multilateral
bank loans as well. Indeed, the training of Chilean officers in
the Panama Canal Zone actually increased, and the White House
enlarged the CIA station in Chile and spent over eight million
dollars on its work until September 1973. Now it moved systematically
and did everything from maintaining constant contact with coup
plotters, whom it encouraged in every way, to fabricating documents
on Cuban control of the police to drawing up arrest lists and
the key targets to take when the coup began.
Allende did nothing to create a counterbalance
to the military, whom he courted with increased funding and cabinet
posts, and the economy suffered from the inevitable reduction
of U.S. aid and the inflationary disorder Frei had bequeathed
it. Chile got some aid from the Soviet bloc, but it was not sufficient,
and when he went to Moscow at the end of 1972 in the hope of obtaining
a hard-currency credit of $500 million, the Russians advised him
to come to terms with the United States rather than fight it and
face disaster- and they then informed Washington of the fact.
He attempted to borrow money elsewhere, with only modest results.
Yet despite the innumerable difficulties, the new government successfully
introduced land reform and basic social programs that helped the
masses, and in the March 1973 congressional elections its vote
increased from 37 percent in 1970 to 43 percent of the total despite
the fact the United States secretly gave $1,428,000 to the opposition.
The middle class, above all, suffered most from inflation and
reform, and the United States covertly funded their destabilizing
transport strikes against the government's policies, generously
aiding the militant opposition.
The officers were almost all from middle-class
families and deeply distressed over their plight. After the March
elections made it clear that the normal political process would
not remove the government, the reticence of a portion of them
to act melted and the coup began on September 11, 1973, killing
Allende within hours and quickly wiping out what little resistance
there was Americans knew of every detail of the planned coup,
and the carefully adled CIA strategy for an efficient operation
was put into practice. A U.S. naval group and air force team quietly
positioned nearby in case the progovemment navy reacted was no
longer deemed useful and was withdrawn. Meanwhile, at least three
thousand people were killed and untold thousands arrested, and
interrogation centers employing torture were set up permanently
throughout the country."
A brutally repressive regime was essential
to America's interests because there was no civilian political
option for it to turn to, and Washington had no hesitation in
immediately endorsing the new order and aiding it, revealing again
its two-decades-long preference for dictators and repressive regimes
in the hemisphere. Chile also proved once more that the United
States could never gracefully accept the verdict of democratic
politics in any nation, where anti-Yankee sentiment was overwhelming
for fear of seeing not only its local investments lost but also
encouraging anti-United States economic legislation elsewhere
in the hemisphere. The coalition ranged against it in Chile was
centrist as well as leftist, revealing that the historically dominant
hemispheric trend toward nationalist economic strategies certain
to constrict, if not exclude, U.S. investment was more vital and
dangerous than ever. Indeed, the very nature of this nationalist
vision created a hemispheric consensus that was politically still
far more widespread and effective, and therefore threatening,
than conventional Left ideologies. Had it survived, the Chilean
example would have posed an unprecedented, grave challenge to
Yankee hegemony.
The Middle East: Toward Protracted Crisis
p224
It was the United States' decisive tilt toward Israel after 1967
that made possible the USSR's growing leverage in the Middle East,
for the Arab nations that Israel threatened most were unable to
obtain all the arms that they desired elsewhere. This fact alone
greatly complicated America's policy insofar as it believed, as
did Kissinger, that its credibility was also involved whenever
Soviet weapons in the hands of non-Communists threatened to defeat
U.S. arms in the hands of its friends. This expanded credibility
doctrine, which the United States applied during the India-Pakistan
crisis in 1971, revealed that while the Nixon Administration would
pursue a surrogate strategy, it would be quite as ready as its
predecessors also to intervene directly in the area, usually confronting
the USSR at the same time, and ultimately remain unable to exercise
self-control. This dual-track approach toward conflict in the
region was not calculated well in advance but was initially a
visceral reaction to immediate events. This was first revealed
for the Nixon Administration during the Jordanian crisis of September
1970, and it has remained the fundamental, and dangerous, contradiction
as well as the premise of U.S. Middle Eastern policy since then.
Since 1968 Nasser had energetically tried
to increase Soviet aid and advisers to his nation, and by 1970
had succeeded to a greater extent than ever before. In the summer
of 1970, Nasser and King Hussein decided to move against the radical
elements of the Palestine Liberation Organization stationed in
both their nations but primarily in Jordan. The now familiar tragic
imbroglio in the Arab world broke out when Hussein on September
15 began to stamp out the PLO and when Syria sent tanks and troops
to protect them. At this point, in constant touch with and supporting
Hussein, Washington announced the dispatch of aircraft carriers
and other ships into the eastern Mediterranean and alerted its
airborne troops. And while Kissinger warned the bewildered Russians
that they would be held responsible should their Syrian "client"
not withdraw, the United States also urged the Israelis to prepare
to invade if required to save Hussein. Israel in turn demanded
and got a U.S. promise to intervene should it become the target
of a Soviet or an Egyptian attack. Reassured, Israel mobilized,
and on September 23 the thoroughly frightened Syrians, probably
under Soviet pressure as well, began to leave Jordan. A major
war had been averted. And after trying desperately to keep the
conflict from escalating, Nasser died of a heart attack on September
28.
The Jordan crisis, coming just as the
British were leaving the region, reinforced the United States'
commitment to Iran as its principal ally in the Persian Gulf,
and while the containment of the Soviet-armed radical Iraqis was
Tehran's primary responsibility, it was also to assure that radicals
not undermine the Gulf states. This reliance "on the central
importance of Iran to the safeguarding of the American . . . interest
in the oil region of the Persian Gulf," as President Jimmy
Carter's national security adviser later described it, was to
continue until 1978, when the Shah's eagerness to spend vast sums
on arms and his pro-Americanism led to his undoing and to a historic
new challenge to the United States.'
Israel, meanwhile, became the Administration's
principal but not exclusive surrogate in the territory immediately
surrounding it, and also Hussein's guarantor. But Nasser's death
and the emergence of Anwar Sadat as his successor, who expelled
all Soviet advisers in July 1972, soon increased America's options.
From this point onward, relations with Egypt improved dramatically.
Yet until this trend reached its culmination, the White House
relied entirely on Israel, whom they began to arm heavily after
early 1972. And while neither the president nor Kissinger had
ever thought much of Secretary of State William Rogers's December
1969 plan that recognized UN Resolution 242, calling for Israel's
withdrawal from occupied territories, they ceased to press it
altogether because of Israel's adamant opposition. Israel now
exercised a de facto veto on U.S. diplomatic policy in the region
as the reward for its obedience in other domains, even though
the Administration thought Israel often unreasonable. Washington
did not consider the peace process crucial, however, because it
persisted in regarding all regional issues as basically aspects
of Soviet-American rivalry with few purely local roots, and Kissinger's
main goal was to reduce Soviet influence. This was soon to prove
a major error, for, as Kissinger was later to confess, the Soviet
advisers in Egypt were probably a major constraint preventing
Sadat from using his now formidable military power. When on October
6, 1973, the Egyptians struck the completely surprised Israeli
army in Sinai, inflicting huge losses on its tanks and aircraft
over the next weeks, they also irreversibly changed the entire
military, economic, and political situation in the Middle East.
Israel's allegedly invincible army was
now shown to be highly vulnerable, and while the White House warned
Moscow not to intervene, it also did nothing to stop the Soviets
from resupplying the Egyptians when the battle turned against
them. Politically the United States was unwilling to range itself
against the entire Arab world, including its Saudi and Persian
Gulf allies who supported with both words and funds Egypt's surprise
attack and who on October 17 increased the price of oil 17 percent
as the initial step in their profound transformation of the world
oil structure and its relation to the global economy. As the first
reverberations of the October War were felt and a massive oil
boycott was set in train, the United States and the USSR united
in the UN to try to terminate the fighting.
The radical changes that were to occur
in the Middle East after 1973 revealed that the United States'
two-decade effort to assume primary control over the area had
been a chimera based on illusions and false assumptions from the
inception. The British had been completely supplanted, and the
Arab world had exploited Soviet willingness to provide enormous
quantities of arms even though not a single Marxist state had
been established. It was perfectly obvious that nationalism was
far more potent than radicalism and that the festering Arab-lsraeli
conflict guaranteed that this would remain the case, making anti-Americanism
inevitable. "In retrospect," George McGhee, one of the
key architects of Middle East policy, admitted in 1974, "this
was always a greater danger in the Arab States than communism
itself, which didn't find fertile ground among the Arabs."
By 1974 the United States, despite Iran, Saudi Arabia, and Israel
by its side, was losing control over Middle Eastern oil-the main
objective of its efforts there since 1945.
The quickening cycle of change and crisis
meant that the region would never again be relegated to the sidelines,
and it would increasingly become a central challenge to U.S. foreign
policy. Indeed, by the 1970s the Middle East had become the area
most likely to draw America into a major war that ultimately risked
direct conflict with the Soviet Union itself. Given the vast responsibilities
in the region the United States was prepared to assume and . its
need both to depend on and protect surrogate regimes of questionable
ability, only unresolvable crises loomed before it.
p227
The United States and the Changing World
Economy
The New Relationship in Oil, and Raw Materials
In petroleum, the United States' standing
fundamentally altered after 1945 its national share of world output
fell from 61 percent in 1938 to 14 percent in 1978, while its
domestic proved reserves dropped to 5 percent of the global total
in 1979 (at a time when it was consuming 28 percent of the world's
oil) compared to 56 percent in the Middle East. By 1960 the United
States was importing 19 percent of its supply, then 30 percent
in 1972 and 45 percent in 1979, and while the Middle East and
North Africa had provided a negligible part of its imports in
1970, by 1980 nearly half of American crude oil imports came from
those areas. Authoritative industry sources in 1972 expected the
U.S. need for oil in 1985 to be twice the 1970 volume.
By the late 1960s it was clear that the
gap between world oil demand and supply was growing wider, and
the bargaining position of the surplus producers increased with
it. In 1970 Libya broke the unity of U.S. buyers and showed the
Middle East that it could use the Organization of Petroleum Exporting
Countries (OPEC) to jack up their revenues, which had risen relatively
slowly after the organization was formed in 1960. Given the fact
that the seven major international companies earned far more in
the Eastern Hemisphere than elsewhere, during the period before
the October 1973 War the world oil system began to undergo profound
changes that the war brought to a head for ostensible political
reasons but primarily because the economics of the industry had
been shifting in favor of the producing countries, and against
the United States, for some years.
In the case of non-petroleum raw materials,
the deep concern among all decisionmakers over the depletion of
U.S. supplies that the Korean War had triggered, and that the
Paley Commission in 1952 had warned required decisive action,
by the late 1950s had declined sharply with lower prices and surpluses.
By the mid-1960s there was an equanimity in most high-level government
circles that the expansion of reserves and acceptable prices would
continue indefinitely. Raw materials as a motivating factor in
U.S. policy in the Third World remained a major consideration
mainly among American companies and officials involved with specific
resource-rich nations. Critics of U.S. policy who still stressed
its objective significance were dismissed as neo-Marxists.
While there is no doubt that many of Paley's
prognostications were incorrect, U.S. dependence on raw materials
imports after 1960 nonetheless grew absolutely as well as in qualitative
new ways. Adjusted for inflation, U.S. minerals imports doubled
from 1950-54 to 1965-69, and increased by half again over the
next five years. As a share of consumption, iron and ferroalloys
imports grew from 32 percent in 1950-54 to 44 percent in 1975-79,
and all other metal ores, after declining for a time, by 1970-75
were 40 percent of consumption. While world reserves of most metals
rose after 1950, often dramatically, almost all the growth was
outside the United States, principally in the Third World. U.S.
deficits and requirements increased by virtually any criterion.
Of eighty-six materials Congress's Office of Technology Assessment
reviewed, the United States was self-sufficient in twenty-two
of them in 1984, while fifty came from diverse or stable sources.
Fourteen absolutely vital materials, without which the United
States literally could not function militarily and would be seriously
hobbled economically, came primarily from central and southern
Africa as well as the USSR.
Indeed, by the early 1970s, U.S. experts
on raw materials issues had reached a much higher level of understanding
in assessing their importance, focusing not only on quantities
and shares but also on the vital role of specific materials whose
qualitative significance escaped crude numbers. To repeat, technologically
advanced industries have a far greater need than ever for relatively
small quantities, in dollar and weight terms, of certain materials,
and chromium, cobalt, manganese, and the platinum group were probably
the most important, and since 1950 these were almost entirely
imported. Official experts increasingly measured their true value
in terms of multipliers of twenty-five to thirty times: for example,
$10 million worth of materials in technologically based industries
made possible about $250 million worth of economic activity, and
some estimates were even higher. "This approximately $32
billion [of raw materials]," the former director of the U.S.
National Commission on Materials Policy told Congress at the end
of 1973, "is the life blood of a $1,152 billion economy,"
and nearly half of it was imported.' The irony of all these data
was that the United States' objective economic need to exploit
freely the world's poorer nations was greatest at that time after
1945 that its power to control them was relatively the weakest.
Confronting the economic and political
problems emerging from these statistics therefore preoccupied
the Nixon Administration after 1973 to an extent it had scarcely
imagined possible four years earlier, largely because, given the
economics of the situation, a crisis between the United States
and oil-producing nations was long overdue, for the United States
no longer had the capacity, as in 1956, to pump sufficient oil
to withstand concerted action from the oil-exporting nations to
increase prices. The combined demand of all the industrial capitalist
nations made the astonishing stability in oil prices that had
persisted until 1970 too assailable. The large oil companies maintained
their solidarity on prices until September 1970, when Libya demanded
that Occidental Petroleum pay 20 percent over the world price.
When the seven major oil companies refused to supply Occidental
with alternative sources, it succumbed to Libyan pressures. Oil
prices more than doubled in the three years prior to October 1973
as the OPEC nations began picking off other vulnerable companies.
In January 1971 the Nixon Administration tried to thwart OPEC's
refusal any longer to subsidize Western economic growth with cheap
oil. But it found after sending a mission to the Middle East that
its military surrogates in both Iran and Saudi Arabia were unwilling
to forgo a far greater share of oil profits, and Saudi Arabia,
indeed, began to link oil prices to U.S. policy toward Israel.
Well before the October 1973 War, official American circles were
publicly discussing an imminent conflict with the major exporters.
The oil shock following the October War
was a historic turning point in the economic relations between
the oil-producing Third World and the major industrial capitalist
nations, the United States above all, and it strained traditional
political alliances to the limit as nations rushed to protect
themselves. From $1.26 a barrel in 1970, the OPEC price rose to
$9.40 in 1974 and $24 at the end of 1979. The United States' bill
for imports, which was $2.8 billion in 1970 and nearly doubled
over the next two years as the crisis began, was $24.3 billion
in 1974 and over twice that by 1979-an increase of twenty times!
The Arab world cut off exports to the United States temporarily
during the October War, but most of America's NATO allies and
Japan ostentatiously distanced themselves from Washington's policies
in order to escape the boycott and ruination in Arab hands. "It
was not," Kissinger later recalled, "one of the finer
moments of allied relations."
With both the Shah of Iran and King Faisal
of Saudi Arabia joining in the fray to exploit their new unity
and leverage, the White House felt utterly betrayed, and its helplessness
was reflected in occasional vague threats over coming months and
years to invade Saudi Arabia should it prove necessary. The "oil
weapon," as Kissinger called it, proved the most effective
assault upon American interests since 1945, greatly accelerating
a transformation of the world economy and the U.S. position in
it that was already well under way. The Gulf states became rich
beyond imagination, imposing not only the energy question but
also the threat of the use of the vast horde of petrodollars for
political purposes as vital issues defining U.S. relations not
merely with the Third World but especially with its allies. Oil
... pushed Washington's military focus sharply toward the control
of the Gulf and reduced its ability to cope with less dramatic
and less costly but nonetheless vital challenges elsewhere in
the Third World.
The crisis in oil also spilled over to
other raw materials, and the price of metal ores about doubled
between 1972 and 1974, even though most U.S. officials dealing
with the problem during the early 1970s had already predicted
an imbalance in supply and demand in the near future-and therefore
higher prices. Responding to such issues preoccupied leading decisionmakers
to an unprecedented extent, and an intensive and quite sophisticated
focus on raw materials issues, and their policy implications,
prevailed among them for the remainder of the decade. Greater
use of stockpiling reduction of consumption, and innumerable schemes
were discussed widely throughout this period, creating much more
interest in Africa as Latin America's share of U.S. minerals imports
fell throughout the 1960s.
OPEC revealed that it was possible for
the poorer oil nations to stop subsidizing the prosperity in the
industrial capitalist nations, and producers of other raw materials
made a concerted effort to revive commodity associations as effective
bargaining tools to increase their share of the world's blessings-leading
to an immediate confrontation with the United States. "The
United States has always been lukewarm in its enthusiasm for commodity
agreements," the assistant secretary for African affairs
admitted in September 1972 with characteristic understatement,
"and at times even formally opposed their use." Diplomatic
niceties alone had kept it from outright denunciation of nearly
all of them, but its rare support for a few was essentially part
of a maneuver to control them. In 1969, unable to manipulate the
international sugar agreement that the United States had dominated
since 1937, it dropped out of it. Expanded markets, more efficient
production, and such slogans were ritual American responses to
Third World demands for stable and fair prices. In the aftermath
of October 1973, the bitter arguments between the United States
and those seeking to raise prices revealed that what was at stake
was the division of the world's wealth rather than equity, and
that sheer power would dictate the outcome of disputes.
The State Department in January 1974 had
concluded that the chance of raw materials' prices paralleling
those for oil was unlikely in the short run save in copper and
bauxite, but given that "the longer run U.S. dependence on
foreign sources of raw materials is likely to increase . . . [w]e
should consider appropriate steps to reduce the possibility and
effectiveness of aggressive action by producers to deprive us
of adequate supplies." Mexico and Venezuela especially took
the lead in promoting new commodity associations and resuscitating
old ones, and the Nixon Administration responded brutally to these
"tactics of confrontation," as Kissinger described them.
The Latin nations were particularly anxious to develop united
efforts because most had little oil relative to their population.
"Such tactics are particularly inappropriate for the Western
Hemisphere," Kissinger warned, "where they threaten
to repudiate a long tradition of cooperative relations with the
United States. ,,6 Those relations now were reduced to their barest
economic essence.
In 1975 the United States therefore rewrote
its trade act to "preempt" and provide "a deterrent
against new commodity cartels" by denying nations joining
them tariff preferences, notwithstanding its nominal traditional
commitment to freer trade and commerce rather than aid. The Administration
had little to worry about in reality because it had ample alternative
import sources in most cases, and aspiring cartel members were
often disunited for a variety of reasons. At the end of 1975 it
sought to modify its materialist, self-serving image by proposing
convoluted schemes involving the World Bank and private investors
to create a hodgepodge of cosmetic changes that would bypass Third
World efforts and give a new World Bank institution a "facilitating
role as third party with the host country and the foreign investor."
None of the schemes was realized.
U.S. militancy in defending its economic
interests as a consumer was scarcely new, nor were the renewed
threats to "bring to bear available political and economic
influence to get a satisfactory resolution" of disputes over
everything from trade to protecting its overseas investors. American
multinationals were also exporters of raw materials, and they
profited enormously from post-1973 price increases. The exact
extent of this gain is impossible to calculate, save for the oil
companies. Suffice it to say that U.S. direct investment abroad
in 1960 was $32 billion, with 35 percent of it in the Third World,
while by 1982 it had risen to $ 185 billion, but only 21 percent
of it was in the Third World. The profits from all foreign investments
have been consistently far higher, usually two to three times,
than those within the United States, and returns in the Third
World have been, by far, the most lucrative of all. In 1982 they
accounted for 39 percent of all profits from foreign investments.
International Banks
p232
Given the major changes occurring in the world economic structure
damaging both the Third World and traditional U.S. power at the
same time, it was inevitable that American leaders would seek
to exploit far more systematically those international official
banking institutions that the Eisenhower Administration and its
successors had begun to shift to as more effective and subtle
means for attaining their goals. Had the multilateral banks not
existed as highly developed instruments by the mid-1960s, then
it would have been essential for Washington to create them, but
they stand out as a brilliant example of U.S. prescience after
1945 on how to seek to extend its hegemony over the world economy.
Without them, America's economic power and its control over basic
economic trends in the Third World would have declined much more
than they did.
The United States effectively dominated
both the World Bank and the IMF as well as their affiliates, and
in 1974, a total of 41 percent of the bank's top managers were
Americans, and the president was always a U.S. citizen. An official
U.S. review in 1982 of its postwar ability to define major multilateral
bank decisions concluded that it had succeeded in the great majority
of cases where it exerted pressure.
p233
Washington's growing emphasis on using multilateral banks as the
key instruments of a neocolonial policy to integrate Third World
nations into a United States-led and -guided world economy was
the subject of frequent detailed internal official economic analyses,
which made it clear that after decades of experience the banks'
negative effects were both understood and desired, even though
their authors personally sometimes also had other objectives in
mind. In October 1972 the AlD's Bureau for Program and Policy
p235
The share of the total profits of the thirteen largest U.S. international
banks earned abroad rose from 17 percent in 1970 to 49 percent
in 1976, for there was a much greater demand for their funds outside
the United States. The combined assets of the twenty-one largest
U.S. commercial banks operating abroad at the end of 1975 were
twenty times the lending resources of the IMF and the EEC special
facility combined. Compared to these banks, direct corporate investment
seemed paltry as a source of capital, and in various ways state-sponsored
economic projects in many Latin nations became means both of independent
economic development and deeper entanglement with world capital.
But for a relatively brief time some of the Third World nations
could borrow freely without accepting strict limits on their use
of funds or economic policies. The Latin debt to official creditors
in 1979 was less than it was in 1960, but its total debt in 1979,
most of it to private banks, was now far greater than ever. To
some extent, the main beneficiaries of the dizzying rise in the
price of oil were the banks that processed the largest share of
the gains. From the U.S. government's viewpoint, all this meant
that unless countermeasures were taken, its ability to define
the Third World's economic policies was more in doubt than ever.
And from the private banks' vantage, some regulation was essential
if they were ever to be repaid the interest and principal owed
to them.
The debt itself provided the United States
with the handle it needed to attempt to reimpose its hegemony
via the official banks. Brazil's debt as a percentage of its exports
grew from 36 percent in 1973 to 61 percent in 1979, while Mexico's
nearly tripled, to 64 percent. By 1976 both private bankers and
U.S. officials began to converge on a solution for their common
anxieties in the form of a greatly expanded critical role for
the IMF in the lending activities of private banks, especially
when they had to renegotiate more loans to bail out those nations
inevitably falling into distress. Their goal, in the words of
a U.S. Senate report, was to "give the IMF more clout in
putting pressure on deficit countries to undertake the often painful
and politically difficult adjustment policies required to bring
their external accounts into balance," measures the banks
were least able to impose without turning the political ire of
the population of many states against them. As the revised IMF
charter assigned it new surveillance functions, IMF "conditionality"
increasingly became the impetus for political crises and food
riots in a growing number of countries as hapless nations attempted
to meet its inflexible, ritual demands to cut social services
of all kinds. This struggle remains central to the experiences
of our own times.
The Philippines: Creating a Revolution
p249
The 1969 election that returned Ferdinand Marcos to power in one
of the most manipulated and violent, and surely the costliest,
electoral campaign in Philippine history exhausted the nation
both politically and economically and marked a turning point in
its development. The economic difficulties it brought to a head
were the logical culmination of years of error and neglect, but
the political crisis was a qualitatively new phenomenon, the outcome
of a far greater public awareness that both the nation's traditional
oligarchic politics and leaders were unable to resolve the massive
problems of the society-and thereby ceased to be relevant. It
was also the result of an incipient civil war within the traditional
elite between those nationalist economic constituencies demanding
more than conventional opportunistic politics to protect and advance
their interests, and the dominant politicians who since 1946 had
treated the state simply as a vehicle for self-enrichment-between
those who were eager to serve U.S. interests and those ready to
cut the economic cords that still bound the nation. It was this
merger of structural economic problems with a new political consciousness
that was to cause the Philippines to veer away from inherited
methods of confronting problems and toward radical alternatives.
These trends presented the United States with altogether new challenges
in its Asian neo-colony.
The enormous cost of the 1969 election
to the Philippine treasury accelerated the massive deterioration
of the economy, but it did not initiate it. Structurally, the
economy was weak by virtue of its export dependence and strategic
U.S. control over it, which would have caused the nation's debt
to rise dramatically even if there had not been spectacular corruption.
The 1969 election expenses did, however, produce a sharp inflation
of 15 to 20 percent annually over the next three years, running
up huge government deficits and forcing it to borrow, and the
external public debt nearly doubled over the next year and rose
sharply every year thereafter. The country was beginning to fall
into the standard Third World debt trap, with all of its consequences.
To cope with his problems, Marcos had no alternative but to call
upon the World Bank to help him, and to get funds from the consultative
group it set up to manage the debt. He accepted the bank's advice
to devalue the peso again in February 1970 by 60 percent to stimulate
exports. Given the sharp drop in the prices of its main raw materials
exports on the world market over the next two years, the bank's
cure only aggravated the nation's troubles, inflation included,
and compounded the political difficulties Marcos confronted at
the very point he was facing a new form of political opposition.
p251
Nationalism rather than the Left remained the origin of Washington's
immediate problem. Estimating the state of the Left in April 1972,
American experts dismissed the Huks as inconsequential, with most
now mere criminals operating near U.S. bases. The Maoist New People's
Army (NPA) of the newly formed Communist Party (CPP) had gone
from 390 hard-core members in 1969, with an equivalent number
of supporters, to 379 in 1971 and perhaps 10 times that many supporters-in
a nation of 37 million people. While this figure was so small
as to appear ludicrous, the Americans did note that the NPA, unlike
the Huks, had managed to spread teams to a sufficiently larger
number of islands to pose greater logistic challenges than the
Huks had been able to do, and that they "have a much better
reputation than the Philippine Constabulary who have been cited
for stealing, intimidating and taking what they need without reimbursement."
It was perfectly obvious from such information that the tiny Left's
only hope in 1972 was not in its own forces but rather in the
intensification of the structural and organizational deficiencies
of the existing society-over which it had no control. The system's
demise, if it came, would at least at its beginning stages be
the result of its own internal contradictions.
It was in this context that Marcos moved
toward martial law and an end to the ambiguities of Filipino politics,
because, unable to co-opt his opponents, he could only suppress
them or relinquish power. Public discussion of martial law increased
after the summer of 1971, and American officials either favored
it or remained neutral. "The Philippines needs a strong man,
a man on horseback to get the country organized and going again,"
the embassy's political officer during the post-1969 years wrote.
In the weeks preceding the proclamation of martial law on September
23, 1972, it was widely believed that Marcos would use alleged
"Communist" actions and plots, linking them with his
Liberal opponents, to abolish the nation's precarious period of
constitutionalism. It was fully evident by this time that the
main political trends emerging from Filipino democracy were more
threatening than at any time since 1960. If Marcos lost power,
then American strategic, economic, and political interests would
suffer greatly. It was scarcely conceivable, given its readiness
to act in nations where the stakes were far smaller, that Washington
would passively accept such an ignominious end to its colonial
experience and its long endeavor to show the world how its beneficent
efforts could build a model Third World society.
The United States and Martial Law
p252
The U.S. view of its interests in the Philippines prior to September
1972 had not altered since 1945, and it involved retention and
uninhibited use of two major and six small bases, "to avoid
injury to established U.S. enterprise, i.e., to foster an orderly
transition from the special relationships embodied in Laurel-Langley,
and to promote to the maximum feasible extent the continued participation
of American enterprise," as well as stability within the
Philippines itself. "Moderating Philippine economic nationalism"
was far more important than any other immediate American concern,
and Washington clearly preferred that "technocrats"
administer economic policy. No American official working on the
Philippines in 1972 believed there was a danger from Communists.
The embassy regarded Marcos highly because while he was both described
in the U.S. press, as well as known to be, extremely corrupt,
he had also proved himself to be the most receptive of A all major
political leaders, notwithstanding a certain populist flamboyance
and bouts of opportunism. But most important of all in the summer
of 1972, top American leaders had their hands full elsewhere,
above all with Vietnam and the U.S. presidential race, and they
were indifferent to the fast-moving developments in Manila. It
was left to the U.S. ambassador, Henry Byroade, to cope with the
issue, and when he was informed during August that martial law
would soon be declared, he simply told Marcos that it would be
far more palatable in Washington were it justified as essential
to cope with Communists. By mid-September its imminent announcement
was public knowledge, and the CIA even obtained its text. Marcos
decided to check by phone with a preoccupied Nixon, who told him,
depending on the account, either to go ahead or raised no objections.
Marcos saw Byroade the day before proclaiming martial law and
told him that he would now be able to reverse the Quasha decisions
and protect U.S. economic interests.
Marcos exploited his opportunity to the
hilt, closing down all opposition papers and arresting Liberal
and nationalist leaders as well, of course, as those leftists
who had not already used the ample advance warnings to escape.
AU told, about fifty thousand people were detained, not including
those under house arrest, and by 1975 there were still six thousand
in Marcos's prisons, including Aquino, his most redoubtable Liberal
opponent. No one in Washington objected to this wholesale suppression
of civil liberties-a long-familiar, welcome procedure in the U.S.
conception of how best to run Third World regimes.
Marcos had arranged for his executive
secretary, Alejandro Melchor, to arrive in the United States just
as martial law was declared, and after briefing Washington officials
and the World Bank on Marcos's plans to help both U.S. business
and introduce some overdue reforms, he obtained a pledge of far
greater World Bank aid and met with most important American companies
involved in the Philippines, assuring them that there was no more
danger from nationalist legislation and Supreme Court rulings.
On October 3 Marcos issued a new foreign investment decree aimed
at attracting oil and mining capital. U.S. oilmen waxed enthusiastic,
and The New York Times' Manila correspondent in late October concluded,
'The American business community in the Philippines has greeted
with relief the results of the Sept. 23 declaration of martial
law." It would mean the end of economic anti-Americanism,
at the least, and Marcos's subsequent declarations for free enterprise
and foreign investment, and abolition of unions and strikes, sustained
this glow of mutual admiration over the next years. The honeymoon,
however, assumed that both sides would help each other, and Marcos
very much needed aid at this point in time.
In essence, the U.S. relationship to the
authoritarian regime changed from a defensive to a dominant one
after twelve years of anti-American agitation. The economic aspect
of this restoration was crucial, given the immense debts Marcos
had run up, and Washington's responsibility for influencing the
economy, in accordance with its global policy, was transferred
mainly to the World Bank and the IMF. U.S. bilateral economic
aid dropped from $125 million in 1973 to $72 million (mainly as
loans) in 1979, while military aid during 1973-76-essentially
a rental payment for use of the bases-was twice as high as the
average for the preceding four years. Political relations with
Marcos during these years were excellent, his qualities-corruption
not withstanding-much appreciated, save for one gnawing concern
that was to remain in the background throughout this period but
that was later to emerge as a serious problem: his wife, Imelda.
The United States had no experience with
such a person anywhere in the Third World. When William H. Sullivan
replaced Byroade in spring 1973 he raised the first alarm regarding
a woman he regarded as shrewd, consummately ambitious, and astonishingly
corrupt and incompetent. It was clear she wished to succeed her
husband eventually and establish a dynasty, but for the moment
that danger was more abstract than real. For while Ferdinand could
perform services in aborting the nationalist momentum that was
gathering, Imelda might wreck everything that had been accomplished.
This problem was all the greater because of the highly personalized
nature of the regime Marcos was creating.
Marcos in his own way remained enigmatic,
pursuing many diverse and essentially conflicting policies at
the same time-above all, the aggrandizement of his own power.
Ready to evoke nationalist, populist, and even neutralist rhetoric
if it suited his purposes, he also retained a sufficient amount
of economic protectionist legislation to preserve the national
bourgeoisie. Yet he opened the door wide to foreign investors
in fact, if not always with comprehensive legislation, at the
same time allowing pliable technocrats to play an unprecedented
new role in conjunction with World Bank and IMF advisers. This
technocratic impulse, which the United States especially encouraged
despite its readiness also to tolerate Marcos's venality, he more
than counteracted with what was later called "crony capitalism,"
the transfer of huge private and public funds and privileges to
his family and allies, as well as probably the greatest amount
of personal corruption (in absolute rather than relative terms)
in any Third World nation since 1945.
In the short run Marcos was America's
puppet, granting it economic privileges and base rights, but he
also ignored much that it desired to see accomplished. But in
the long run he so traumatized Filipino life and society, creating
all of the essential preconditions for the emergence of a powerful
Left opposition, that the problems facing the United States, though
very different, were far greater by the end of his regime than
ever. And it was the threat of his wife continuing the rape of
the nation that eventually compelled Washington to distance itself
somewhat from him. For while Marcos was ready to make a tactical
alliance with the United States, ultimately he was acting on behalf
of his own account, and this was the most recurrent of all the
U.S. dilemmas in relying on Third World dictators. America wanted
puppets, but efficient ones, and it was never to find them anywhere.
While income distribution became somewhat
more inequitable after 1970, reaching 59 percent for the richest
fifth in the early 1980s, it was the decisive shift within the
elite itself that comprised the most significant change in the
economy and power. Marcos decided to reduce drastically the economic
holdings of his premartial law political enemies, especially among
the Liberals, and he transferred these to his family and closest
political allies. Members of the traditional oligarchy who were
ready to collaborate with him, and there were many, were left
in peace. And, more generally, he allocated immense contracts,
concessions, and cash subsidies, amounting to virtual gifts, to
his cronies. Suffice it to say that in the year after Marcos's
fall in February 1986, the new government sequestered 181 companies
of his 5 closest cronies, 2 of them relatives, and nearly 100
companies of his other assorted allies. Together they possessed
56 radio and TV stations, as well as immense tracts of land, buildings,
and much else. Government loans to just 10 of his cronies amounted
to at least $2.4 billion. Marcos's own fortune is still not fully
assessed, but estimates run up to $15 billion, and $5 billion
is a conservative figure. Attempting to provide an analytically
coherent description of this system defies structured categories
because its capriciousness and contradictory nature makes it too
convoluted, for Marcos's "New Society," as he called
it, was anything but a stable, rationalized, and predictable order.
The net effect of such "gangsterist" systems, which
existed in China until 1949 and Latin America later, is that they
traumatize already fragile societies and accelerate those social
and economic developments that produce a strong Left opposition,
putting revolution on the agenda where it might otherwise not
be.
In the case of the Philippines, while
Marcos levied a direct charge on the fortunes of the politically
ambitious rival oligarchs, the greatest cost was indirect, and
the people paid it. It was here that the United States to some
extent lost control of the process, for while it sought primarily
to protect its own economic and strategic position, using Marcos
as a tool to do so, it scarcely realized that he, like so many
like him elsewhere, would further pauperize the nation and foster
a far more powerful Left challenge to American interests.
Marcos also basically and permanently
altered the framework of power that existed in the nation since
1946 by transforming the military, which had always been relatively
small and apolitical, into a personal instrument, in the process
creating a crucial new arbiter of power and politics such as existed
in many, even most, Third World nations. One of his first acts
after declaring martial law was to promote officers he could trust,
increase the pay of all of them, and raise living allowances for
the lower ranks. He systematically doubled the size of the army
by 1977, advancing loyal officers from his home province of llocos
Norte, and recruiting soldiers from there as well. Far more important
yet was his dramatic enlargement of officers' administrative and
judicial responsibilities in normally civilian posts, making them
key political executives also. The United States welcomed this
trend in the Philippines as it did everywhere in the Third World,
believing that since they had brained thousands of these officers
they presumably would also become technocratic "modernizers"
and advance American goals. Marcos, however, had far better control
over them at the inception, but his own crony officers created
a split within the officer corps that later further eroded the
stability of his regime. In this role the military also became
key corruptionists, habituated to the perquisites and exercise
of state power.
Confronting
the Third World
Foreign Policy watch
US and Third World
Home Page